Breaking News
Get 40% Off 0
💰 Warren Buffett reveals a $6.72 billion stake in Chubb Copy Portfolios

David Miles, External Member of the Monetary Policy Committee: Central bank asset purchases and financial markets

By Bank of EnglandJun 26, 2013 07:16AM ET
 
Speech given by
David Miles, External Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England
At the Global Borrowers & Investors Forum
London
26 June 2013

I would like to thank Jochen Schanz and Arpad Morotz for research assistance, and others for helpful
comments. The views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the
Bank of England or other members of the Monetary Policy Committee.

The nature of the effects of large scale asset purchases by central banks is controversial, important and of immediate relevance to policy. I want to consider the evidence on the impacts of such asset purchases, assess whether they are causing distortions in financial markets – rather than provide support for demand in
the wider economy – and offer some thoughts on how the exceptional setting of monetary policy we see in the UK today might ultimately be normalised.

Much of the most vocal and opinionated analysis of the impacts of central bank asset purchases – quantitative easing (QE) – strikes me as somewhat contradictory. Some people seem to believe that large scale asset purchases by central banks have created a bubble in many asset markets and that stopping such purchases (let alone reversing them) must cause big falls in prices. Others take the view that these central bank purchases are ineffective in stimulating demand in the wider economy. I think the evidence for either of these positions is weak. But some people believe both things – a position that I think is also contradictory as well as being profoundly pessimistic.

To make much headway it is important to be clear at the outset what a bubble is. Language matters. One must distinguish between the proposition that such asset purchases have made financial market prices higher than they would have been – which I think is true – and that such prices have been pushed far above
what the economic fundamentals suggest is warranted, which is what a bubble is. My reading of the evidence suggests that it is more likely that central bank asset purchases have moved the prices of many private sector assets closer towards what the underlying economic conditions warrant rather than that they
have driven prices far above such levels. I want to look at that evidence and also think about what the impact on the wider economy is of asset prices having been held up relative to where they might have been.

I also want to look ahead to think about what might happen when monetary policy is once again normalised.
I do not think we should be in any hurry in the UK to move the monetary policy dials back to more normal settings – indeed it might well be right for the next move in the UK to push them even further to give more support to demand. But thinking about how policy will ultimately be normalised – and what the effects will be – is essential in thinking about how far the dials should be pushed away from normal in the near term. I will come back to this later.

Asset purchases and bubbles
I think the claim that QE has artificially boosted the prices of many assets to bubble levels does not stand up.
But it is true that in purchasing financial assets central banks – certainly the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee – have deliberately and consciously raised the demand for these assets and that will have supported their prices. Supporting asset prices helps to support growth, because it means that many companies find it easier to raise funds and because it means that household borrowers face lower longer term interest rates. By keeping the value of portfolios of wealth higher than they would have been the spending of many people who own that wealth is supported. Does anyone doubt that many households who, even given the recent sharp sell-off, have seen the value of their ISAs and other stocks and bonds rise over the past few years would have been less inclined to spend had these savings instead fallen sharply in value?

One of the ways that financial crises can have drawn out consequences is when debtors’ balance sheets deteriorate as the assets that they hold lose value. This runs the risk of a negative self reinforcing spiral – a worsening economic situation pushing down on asset prices further depressing demand. By supporting asset prices, QE has helped to ensure that this sort of negative spiral has not happened in the UK. There is a world of difference between supporting asset prices so as to prevent a self-reinforcing downward spiral in values and creating a bubble. Indeed preventing a downward spiral – because it stabilises both asset prices and the wider economy – is pretty much the opposite of blowing up a financial market bubble.

The evidence for a general bubble in asset prices is not very convincing. Before the very recent sharp falls, stock prices had risen strongly over the past year or so. A couple of weeks ago the FTSE All-Share index was about back where it was in the summer of 2007 – having fallen by about 40% between mid 2007 and
early 2009. But in real (inflation-adjusted) terms stocks were still down by about 20% from the peak 2007 level (Figure 1). In real terms stock prices were at about the average level of the past 20 years. Price to earnings ratios on those stocks do not look unusually high. Figure 2 shows that PE ratios are currently significantly below the average in the ten year period leading up to the crisis of 2007-08. That specific ten year period may have been one in which stock prices were somewhat inflated; but current PE ratios – even before the stock market sell off of the past few weeks – are still no higher than averages over much longer periods covering several decades.

Were there to be a bubble in stock prices I would also expect the equity risk premium – the gap between expected returns on a portfolio of stocks and on safe bonds – to have declined to exceptionally low levels.
Although we cannot measure the equity risk premium accurately, estimates based on a dividend discount model suggest the risk premium on stocks in the FTSE index is actually substantially above the average of recent decades.

What about UK house prices? Average house prices in the UK are – according to some national measures – only 5-10% lower than at the end 2007 peak. Different indices of house prices tell somewhat different stories. But in real terms, that is adjusted for the general rise in the price of goods, they are all down very
substantially. Some measures are down by about 30% in real terms; some are down by about 25%; some measures of house prices in England and Wales (which exclude Northern Ireland where prices are down dramatically) are, in nominal terms, more or less where they were at the end 2007 peak – but even they are
some 20% lower in real terms. Deflating house prices by an index of disposable incomes shows much the same picture: average house prices relative to average disposable incomes are down by between 20% and 30% from peak levels (See Figures 4 and 5).

Yields on UK government debt – both in nominal and real terms – are unusually low (Figures 6 and 7). That is true even after the recent sharp sell-off in gilts following re-assessment of the Fed’s likely scale of asset purchases. Part of the low level of gilt yields reflects a belief that the Bank of England is likely to keep Bank
Rate at relatively low levels for some time yet. Part of it is likely to reflect a substantially higher perceived level of risk now relative to before the financial train wreck of 2007-8. That puts a premium on relatively safe assets like gilts. So there are good reasons why yields on safe government bonds should be low today. I think some people are far too quick to label this a “bubble” – which I would define as a level of prices far removed from what can be expected given the fundamental economic forces at work in the wider economy.

The fact is that with output remaining depressed relative to activity levels before the crisis of 2007-08 and with inflation close to target in many countries central banks are not expected to raise the short term rates they control back to pre-crisis levels for some time. It is seen as likely that short term nominal interest rates for years to come will remain below levels considered normal in the years before the financial crisis. So we should expect to see forward rates implied by the prices of government bonds well below pre-crisis levels for some years ahead – which is precisely what we see in the UK. But looking more than 7 or so years down the road the forward rates now on gilts – which are a guide to expectations on where Bank Rate might then be – are not very different from what they were at the start of 2007. At that time the forward rate relevant to 2021 (which in 2007 was a 14 year forward rate) was about 4%, which is close to today’s forward rate for 2021. In fact longer term forward rates are higher now than in early 2007, before the crisis. Shifts in term premia make it hard to certain how to interpret all this, but the idea that there is clearly a bubble in the gilts market does not really stand up.

For corporate bonds there is even less evidence of a bubble. Instead what we have seen in recent years is a partial reversal of the dramatic rises in the spread of yields over gilts that came in the immediate aftermath of the financial crisis (figure 8). That collapse in the price of corporate bonds in early 2009 has been followed
by a recovery – though an uneven one – in market prices. Values of corporate bonds recovered strongly from the Spring of 2009 as the Bank of England and other central banks cut policy rates to near zero and then bought huge quantities of government bonds, stimulating demand for corporate debt. Spreads on corporate bonds widened out again in 2011 – which was one of the reasons for the Bank of England resuming asset purchases. Since then corporate bond spreads have moved lower.

But the spread between corporate bond yields and yields on government bonds remains wider than it was before the financial crisis.
Figure 9 shows a decomposition of that spread which attempts to identify the part due to illiquidity and uncertainty and a part due to expectations of losses on corporate debt. The component due to illiquidity and uncertainty still appears unusually high – suggesting that bond prices still remain somewhat depressed. This
is hardly a bubble.

Asset prices and the wider economy
What is one to make of the uniquely pessimistic, but increasingly widespread, view that QE has both created multiple asset bubbles while having no impact in boosting demand in the economy? What I find implausible about this is the idea that a rise in the value of assets, and a fall in the likely future return on savings, could
have no effect on stimulating someone’s spending. You would have to believe that investment was not at all responsive to a greater availability of funding at a lower required return. Is that really plausible? You would also need to believe that the wealth effect – that is the positive impact on confidence and spending that higher wealth brings – does not work. I can certainly believe that there are some people who would not respond to higher asset prices by spending more. For some young people the higher value of their existing assets could be more than offset by the prospect of lower returns on future savings which meant they might need to save more to hit a target for wealth far in the future. But I suspect such households are in a small minority. A more common response to the annual statement showing that an ISA
or unit trust was worth more than you might have expected is to spend some of the unanticipated gain. That is what simple economic theory suggests would be the response of older households, and they own far more wealth than younger people.

All in all, I think there is a far more plausible, and rather less sensational, view on the effects of QE. This is that it has supported a wide range of asset prices and that this has caused spending to be higher than it would otherwise have been.

Unwinding QE
What will happen when the asset purchases begin to be unwound? Will the impact on growth and inflation be as large as it had been when the Bank of England purchased assets, just with the opposite sign? I think there are reasons to doubt that, as I will explain shortly. But for the moment let us suppose that this was the
case, and that the MPC decided that monetary policy should be tightened. Then asset purchases would be unwound very gradually, corresponding to the degree of tightening that appears appropriate at the time. So even if growth and inflation were to respond strongly to gilt sales, this is not in itself a problem for monetary
policy. The Bank would then adjust the speed of sales accordingly. But there are good reasons to believe that growth and inflation may respond less to selling gilts than they did to gilt purchases. QE had a considerable impact during the crisis because financial markets were not functioning well. This meant that large-scale purchases of gilts were able to boost the prices on some assets – corporate bonds in particular – because they came at a time when those markets were in a downward
spiral which they helped reverse. It is likely that when bond purchases are reversed financial markets will be working more normally. In more normal markets portfolio changes could be expected to have much less of a price impact because arbitrage and substitutability will be more powerful than when markets are segmented
under stressed conditions.

Together with a colleague at the Bank, I am attempting to obtain a clearer idea about how strong the impact of sales of gilts might be in an environment where there are no limits to arbitrage, and where investors look across all asset classes when deciding which investment strategy to adopt. The only departures we allow
from the complete, perfect markets paradigm is that investors are subject to borrowing constraints. Our initial results using a simple model suggest that when financial markets are working well even quite large changes in portfolios generated by central bank transactions might cause limited changes in prices.

The model that we are developing is highly stylised and makes many simplifications. For example, it abstracts from institutional frictions which might mean that the capacity of markets to absorb large amounts of gilt sales in a short period is likely to be limited. But the initial results appear to suggest that purchasing
assets in times where financial markets are dysfunctional, and selling them when markets work well, might well be part of an optimal monetary policy strategy.
And the unwinding of the Bank’s asset purchases is indeed likely to occur when financial markets are operating more normally. In this environment, investors are much more likely to exploit a perceived difference between the long rate and expected short rates. Risks involved in such trades are also likely to be lower because investors will have a better idea about the total amount of the central bank’s gilt sales than they had about the total amount of gilt purchases during the crisis. That could mean that asset purchases are made when the impact on asset prices and demand in the wider economy is relatively large but assets are sold when the effects on asset prices and demand are much smaller.

Furthermore, it is not clear that the Bank of England’s balance sheet will ultimately shrink to where it had been before the crisis. Banks have learnt that they took excessive liquidity risks before the crisis, and, independently of tighter regulation, are likely to want to hold substantially higher levels of liquid assets in future. Some of these assets are likely to be held in the form of central bank reserves. A natural asset for the central bank to hold to balance the increased amount of commercial bank reserves are government bonds. So it is very far from clear that returning monetary policy to a normal setting means that the Bank of England balance sheet will shrink back to where it was before the crisis.

Figure 10 shows just how small were the most liquid of assets held by banks before the crisis. Even now – after a huge expansion of reserve balances held by banks at the Bank of England – levels of the most liquid banks’ assets (reserves and gilts) relative to bank balance sheets are far smaller than was normal in the 1970s and before. Even if banks only went a small part of the way towards holding portfolios of liquid assets that were considered normal some decades ago, they would be holding far more such assets than was the case before the Bank of England started QE and commercial bank reserves increased sharply.

Conclusions
1. The evidence that asset purchases by central banks have caused generalised bubbles in financial asset prices is weak.
2. In the UK there is more evidence that the Bank’s asset purchases helped to stop an anti-bubble, that is, a downward spiral in asset prices that would have further damaged the real economy and become dangerously self-reinforcing.
3. The market environment in which an unwind of asset purchases takes place is crucial; if done when financial markets are functioning normally a gradual unwind may be smooth.
4. In the UK the unwind of the huge expansion of the central bank balance sheet need not be complete because commercial banks will be very likely to want to hold more reserves than the tiny sliver that they thought adequate before the financial train wreck.










Add a Comment

Comment Guidelines

We encourage you to use comments to engage with other users, share your perspective and ask questions of authors and each other. However, in order to maintain the high level of discourse we’ve all come to value and expect, please keep the following criteria in mind:  

  •            Enrich the conversation, don’t trash it.

  •           Stay focused and on track. Only post material that’s relevant to the topic being discussed. 

  •           Be respectful. Even negative opinions can be framed positively and diplomatically. Avoid profanity, slander or personal attacks directed at an author or another user. Racism, sexism and other forms of discrimination will not be tolerated.

  • Use standard writing style. Include punctuation and upper and lower cases. Comments that are written in all caps and contain excessive use of symbols will be removed.
  • NOTE: Spam and/or promotional messages and comments containing links will be removed. Phone numbers, email addresses, links to personal or business websites, Skype/Telegram/WhatsApp etc. addresses (including links to groups) will also be removed; self-promotional material or business-related solicitations or PR (ie, contact me for signals/advice etc.), and/or any other comment that contains personal contact specifcs or advertising will be removed as well. In addition, any of the above-mentioned violations may result in suspension of your account.
  • Doxxing. We do not allow any sharing of private or personal contact or other information about any individual or organization. This will result in immediate suspension of the commentor and his or her account.
  • Don’t monopolize the conversation. We appreciate passion and conviction, but we also strongly believe in giving everyone a chance to air their point of view. Therefore, in addition to civil interaction, we expect commenters to offer their opinions succinctly and thoughtfully, but not so repeatedly that others are annoyed or offended. If we receive complaints about individuals who take over a thread or forum, we reserve the right to ban them from the site, without recourse.
  • Only English comments will be allowed.
  • Any comment you publish, together with your investing.com profile, will be public on investing.com and may be indexed and available through third party search engines, such as Google.

Perpetrators of spam or abuse will be deleted from the site and prohibited from future registration at Investing.com’s discretion.

Write your thoughts here
 
Are you sure you want to delete this chart?
 
Post
Post also to:
 
Replace the attached chart with a new chart ?
1000
Your ability to comment is currently suspended due to negative user reports. Your status will be reviewed by our moderators.
Please wait a minute before you try to comment again.
Thanks for your comment. Please note that all comments are pending until approved by our moderators. It may therefore take some time before it appears on our website.
 
Are you sure you want to delete this chart?
 
Post
 
Replace the attached chart with a new chart ?
1000
Your ability to comment is currently suspended due to negative user reports. Your status will be reviewed by our moderators.
Please wait a minute before you try to comment again.
Add Chart to Comment
Confirm Block

Are you sure you want to block %USER_NAME%?

By doing so, you and %USER_NAME% will not be able to see any of each other's Investing.com's posts.

%USER_NAME% was successfully added to your Block List

Since you’ve just unblocked this person, you must wait 48 hours before renewing the block.

Report this comment

I feel that this comment is:

Comment flagged

Thank You!

Your report has been sent to our moderators for review
Continue with Google
or
Sign up with Email