Breaking News
Get 40% Off 0
💰 Buffett reveals a $6.7B stake in Chubb. Copy the full portfolio for FREE with InvestingPro’s Stock Ideas tool Copy Portfolios

Andrew Bailey: The new approach to financial regulation

By Bank of EnglandMay 01, 2013 02:36AM ET
 

It is a great pleasure to be here this evening for the Chartered Banker Dinner. President, in
the description of tonight’s dinner you made the important point that the Chartered Institute
supports “ordinary” bankers providing a vital service to their customers at a very difficult time.
I want to speak tonight about the importance of those vital services.

The fact of the matter is that banks are in the dog house, and for reasons that are very well
documented I am afraid. But, in saying that, it would be wrong to believe that this makes
banks irrelevant and unwanted. On the contrary, the financial crisis has through adversity
reminded us of the importance of banks to the functioning and health of the economy and
their role as providers of critical financial services.

Going back in history, it was Walter Bagehot in the 1870s who argued
that the development of joint stock banks played an important part in the growth of
the mid-nineteenth century British economy with its very high degree of openness to world trade.
Scotland played a very major part in that period of economic development, and in the
first official history of the Bank of England, Sir John Clapham recorded that the
Scots loved their banks.

Banks were then important institutions supporting the industrialisation of the British economy
and the trading system that fostered this growth. There is no difference today as the purpose
of banks remains to support activity in the real economy, most obviously by intermediating
between savers and borrowers to enable credit creation. Now an observer could easily
intervene and say “yes, but, what I observe is that they have developed funny ways of going
about it” – complicated products, likewise impenetrable slicing and dicing and re-packaging,
all with the end of supporting bankers’ remuneration on a vast scale. There is some truth of
course in that observation, but let’s not forget that there is a permanent interest of public
policy to ensure the continuous provision of critical financial services to the real economy of
this country, that is protecting savings, enabling payments, credit creation etc. What goes
with this is a very sharp public policy interest in the state of the banking system. This will not
change and nor should it – banks are too important to lose sight of them in ways that
happened in the past.

The job of prudential regulators is to maintain the safety and soundness of the banking
system to ensure the continuity of those critical services to the economy and to the public.
The crisis has been a searing experience for banks and regulators, precisely because at
times they have both failed to fulfil this central objective of maintaining safety and soundness
and hence the continuous supply of critical services to the public.

For what is now not far short of three years we have been working to change the approach to
financial regulation in the UK. We are still working to do that of course, but the difference is
that for the last four and half weeks we have been doing so within the new regulatory
framework of regulation – we are doing it now as the Prudential Regulation Authority and the
Financial Conduct Authority. The prompt for this change of approach has been the severity of
the financial crisis, a crisis that has been through a searing phase of prudential problems –
failing banks – and more recently a conduct phase as the misdeeds and unacceptable
behaviours of the past have been revealed.

On a personal note, recently when my appointment was announced, I was described a
number of times as a veteran of the Bank of England. It was for me a moment of home truth;
28 years is quite a long time in one place, even if the term veteran sits uncomfortably. But it
reminded me that the UK is on its fourth system of financial regulation during that time. The
serious message from this is that institutional structures do matter for the success of public
policy goals and objectives.

The last major reform of the institutional structure in this field was in 1997, when the then
Government reformed monetary policymaking and financial regulation. The results of these
changes were very different. The MPC has in my view been a good example of a successful
institutional structure. You can argue with what the MPC decides month-by month, you can
debate how the framework of policymaking should put into effect the mandate in statute, but
the test of a successful institutional structure of policymaking is that these debates can be
had without undermining the credibility of that institutional framework. As a close observer, I
would say that the MPC has passed this test very well.

I make this point because the same cannot be said over the last fifteen years or so for the
institutional structure around financial stability and supervision. In the 1990s in the UK there
was a very determined effort to build a lasting structure of monetary policy in the wake of the
difficult experiences before that. That institution building effort was about enabling good
policy-making, supported by strong accountability to Parliament and the public, a
determination to be transparent in making policy, and as part of that a commitment to engage
with all the regions of the country. Today, we face the same challenge with financial stability
and supervision.

One thing I should emphasise is that this is a reform of the whole of financial regulation. I say
that because it is easy to conclude from observation of the issues we face as regulators, and
the public debate, that we are just dealing with reforming the regulation of banks. That is not
the case, and what we are doing is not about dragging the rest of the financial services
industry into reform to solve a problem that is in essence only about the banks. We have to
design a system that works effectively for all sectors of the industry.

The 1997 reforms created the FSA as an integrated regulator – by which I mean regulation
which combined Prudential and Conduct of Business in one regulatory body covering the
broad sweep of the financial services industry. The record now shows that this approach did
not work as effectively as it needed to do.

I think there are a number of closely related reasons for this. First, on a rather practical point,
I think it is hard for a single organisation to balance, particularly during a period of crisis, a
wide range of very demanding issues which are individually rightly of great concern to the
public and can come from anywhere in a landscape of around 25,000 authorised firms.
Second, I think the evidence suggests that over the last 15 years there have been periods
when either conduct or prudential supervision has been more in the ascendancy to the
detriment of the other. In the years leading up to the start of the crisis there was a dearth of
prudential supervision, but I am quite prepared to acknowledge that there have been periods
where the opposite has been true. My point here is that I don’t think the system of integrated
regulation demonstrated the ability to deliver a stable equilibrium of conduct and prudential
supervision.

Third, there was something of an inbuilt tendency within integrated regulation to play down
the active debate of issues where conduct and prudential regulators found themselves with
potentially conflicting objectives.
There are several important reasons why reform of financial regulation will in my view be an
important step forward. It starts with establishing very clear public policy objectives for
financial regulation to which we, as the regulators, are fully committed.
For both banks and insurance companies, the PRA will have the objective of promoting the
safety and soundness of firms. Consistent with this objective, it will focus on the potential
harm that firms can cause to the stability of the financial system in the UK. We define a
stable financial system as one that is resilient in providing the critical financial services that
the economy needs. And this supply of services is a necessary condition for a healthy and
successful economy, as demonstrated by the costs imposed by the financial crisis on the
public and society at large.

For insurance companies, the PRA will have the second objective of contributing to securing
an appropriate degree of protection for policyholders. Why do we need a second objective for
insurance? One reason is that in taking out some forms of insurance policies, the public can
become locked into very long-term contracts, much longer often than is the case in banking
with deposit contracts. Bearing this in mind, the public interest I think justifies a second
objective for insurance, which is more directly targeted at the situation of individual
policyholders.

There are a number of important points in this description of the PRA’s objectives. First, the
emphasis on economic well-being as an ultimate goal aligns the supervision of banks and
insurers more closely to the field of macroeconomic policy. This is in line with the definition of
financial stability in terms of the continuity of supply of critical financial services which are
important to the functioning of the economy. Four services stand out here: the protection of
savings; the provision of payment services including access to funds; credit extension; and
risk transfer. This definition is critical to clarifying the public interest-objective in a stable
financial system, and that this public interest can diverge from the private interest of a firm in
profit maximisation without reference to the public interest.

One of the biggest lessons I take from the financial crisis is the need to ensure that the
boards and management of firms appreciate and act consistent with the public interest. To
achieve this end, we need a much better definition of the public interest, which I believe we
now have in the new legislation.

The second important point in terms of the meaning of the PRA’s objectives is that it will not
be the PRA’s role to ensure that no firm fails. Rather, the PRA will seek to ensure that any
firm it regulates that does fail should do so in a way that avoids significant disruption to the
supply of critical financial services. Nevertheless, failure is not costless and there is inherent
uncertainty about whether a firm can fail without damaging the financial system and the
supply of critical services. Consequently, the PRA will expect a given level of resilience to
failure from all firms.

There is another major public interest in the banking system, namely that by becoming too
big to fail, the largest banks have developed an implicit, and in some cases explicit,
dependence on public money. This is unwelcome, for the public, and for the banks, the
former because of the unwanted cost, and the latter because of the intense scrutiny and
oversight of the banks, which must be more intense as long as this state of affairs lasts.

Now, I recognise that we have a lot to do still on resolution planning to be comfortable about
our objective of avoiding a no failure regime and thus solving the Too Big To Fail problem.
For large banks, we are making progress on resolution planning, and this world is different to
five years ago, but we are not there yet by any means. I have a background in resolving
banks, and I regard having the capacity to resolve failed large banks – including the largest –
as the holy grail of resolution. Unlike the legendary Holy Grail, I think there is a good reason
to believe that the objective of being able to resolve large banks that fail can be within our
grasp.

I am very clear that when firms mess up, they should be allowed to fail, and by doing so they
are putting at risk the money of their shareholders and if necessary after that those who
provide debt funding according to levels of seniority. But I am also very clear that really
achieving the objective of avoiding a no failure regime requires a fundamental change of
mindset both inside firms, the authorities and in society more broadly.
Fear of failure is an important conditioner of behaviour in a financial regulator, and achieving
a change on this front depends on establishing a wide acceptance of our approach that
orderly failure which does not compromise our public policy objectives is an acceptable
outcome.

To be clear, we should be criticised where failure compromises those objectives and we
could have taken steps to avoid it. But if failure is orderly, and does not compromise our
public policy objectives, the responsibility should rest with the board and management for
failing to serve the private interest of their shareholders and creditors.

Last on the theme of failure, having firms that are either too big or too important to fail is bad
for competition in the industries that we regulate. An industry where exit is too difficult is one
where entry is likewise inhibited. This is what we see in the banking industry. Embedding
resolution into the public policy objectives of financial regulation matters for two reasons
relevant to competition: first, because, to repeat, exit enables entry; and, second, because if,
as we will, we require new entrants to satisfy us on their resolvability in order to be
authorised, we will lower the barriers and costs of opening for business.

Put simply, if we don’t know how to deal with a failed firm, we will inevitably set a higher
barrier to entry. We have already started to put this new approach into operation.
Resolution of failed firms consistent with the public policy objectives is one key plank of the
new approach to financial regulation. Another key plank concerns the macro prudential
approach to regulation. The legislation has formally established the Financial Policy
Committee (FPC) charged with the primary objective of identifying, monitoring and taking
action to remove or reduce systemic risks with a view to protecting and enhancing the
resilience of the UK financial system.

The FPC also has a secondary objective, to support the economic policy of the Government,
including its objectives for growth and employment.
The root of the introduction of macro-prudential regulation sounds quite obvious, which is to
take into account the impact of financial regulation on the functioning of the real economy.
Obvious you might say – yes, but it wasn’t done in the past.
Macro-prudential regulation is focused on protecting the financial system as a whole. It is
quite simply about ensuring that financial regulation is conducted with an eye on the state of
the economy. In a very big picture sense, there is nothing new about this activity. The
problems of the last five years have emphasised the close links between the health and
behaviour of banks and the condition of the economy. This is a lesson of history, and one
that should not have been forgotten. But, forgotten it was.

A clear objective of macro-prudential policy is to act in a countercyclical fashion – to restrain
booms by acting to tighten regulation, and to seek to dampen the impact of busts.
Unfortunately, the record of the past shows that the behaviour of regulators has not been
consistent with these objectives.

The crisis illustrates the dangers of not applying restraint in what appeared to be good times.
But it requires a very strong culture to allow this type of restraining to happen. The record of
the past indicates that the temptation to “let the good times roll” is deeply embedded in the
political economy of regulation.

Macro-prudential regulation can also lean against the tendency otherwise of micro-prudential
regulators to toughen up their regime in the teeth of the storm. At the heart of this new
approach to making policy is a very simple observation, namely that changes in regulatory
intensity in this area can have an impact on credit availability and thus the performance of
the economy. There are two legs to this argument, and it is important to understand both.
The first leg involves the simple proposition that a well capitalised banking system is more
likely to support credit creation in the economy. We see evidence today of better capitalised
banks tending to see more rapid growth in lending.

It is with this objective in mind that the Bank of England’s Financial Policy Committee has
recommended that the major UK banks as a group should increase their equity capital
resources. The whole point of this action is to enable forward-looking judgemental regulation
to take effect in a system where balance sheet strength is a necessary pre-condition of stronger
lending to the economy as a whole. In the same vein, last summer the
Bank of England and the FSA took steps to implement a clearly
counter cyclical response to a situation which was a problem to for the economy as a whole.

It was an occasion on which responsibilities were well-defined and thus the accountability for
the actions was clear; for the Bank, to introduce the FLS to support lending by bank and
likewise to introduce the extended repo operations for the FSA, to loosen liquidity
requirements and adjust capital buffers to incentivise net new lending.
The key message here is that if the banking system is sufficiently capitalised against future
losses, it can play a full role in counter-cyclical policy which seeks to respond to and lean
against the conditions of the day. That is the essential use of forward-looking judgement,
done with the explicit objective in mind of using financial regulation as a counter-cyclical tool.
At present the Bank of England is pursuing two important objectives: seeking to increase the
resilience of the UK banking system, and, supporting the creation of credit in the UK
economy.

Let me say a few words therefore about the announcement last week to extend the Funding
for Lending Scheme and modify its terms. It is almost a year since we designed and began
the implementation of the current FLS.
That was done against the backdrop of a much more febrile environment in the euro area in
terms of sentiment and a real concern that the risks arising from the euro area situation were
affecting the costs of funding for UK banks and therefore their lending and the economy
more broadly.

Alongside that evidence, we could see that the sum of the projections for lending in the two
years ahead for the UK banks was substantially negative. The case for acting was therefore
strong, but the challenge was also that in its first year, success for the FLS was in some
ways to prevent the most negative outcome for lending, which in an absolute sense would
not look great.

What we have seen over the last year is quite a substantial change in the funding costs of
banks which has fed through into lower lending costs, but more so in terms of the amount of
lending in the mortgage market than for small firms. Funding for the major banks have also
become less disposed, which has probably increased the willingness of banks to compete on
lending. But the uneven pattern of lending meant that we thought it was sensible to increase
the incentives for banks to lend to small firms.
We cannot say that this will conclusively deal with the question of whether the problem is a
lack of loan supply or demand, but we can say that we have used our toolkit to create a big
incentive for banks to lend to small firms.

In summary, there is a strong public interest in the banks, which has been sharpened by the
crisis. One element of that public interest is permanent – the role of banks in supporting the
real economy. Another is permanent, and like the first should be in the category of a given –
namely, good conduct by banks. But the third – the dependence on public money – should
not survive, hence the strong focus on developing bank resolution and ending too big to fail.
President, we all have our work cut-out. You can take pride in the role of the Institute in
supporting the establishment of the Professional Standards Board and their work on the
Code of Professional Conduct and the Professional Standards initiative. As a start, I
understand that at least 70,000 bank staff will go through the Foundation Standard by the
beginning of July this year. This is a big achievement, for which those involved should be
proud. There is a lot more to do I know, but let me congratulate Susan Rice, who has led the
work, and everyone else involved.

Thank you.









Add a Comment

Comment Guidelines

We encourage you to use comments to engage with other users, share your perspective and ask questions of authors and each other. However, in order to maintain the high level of discourse we’ve all come to value and expect, please keep the following criteria in mind:  

  •            Enrich the conversation, don’t trash it.

  •           Stay focused and on track. Only post material that’s relevant to the topic being discussed. 

  •           Be respectful. Even negative opinions can be framed positively and diplomatically. Avoid profanity, slander or personal attacks directed at an author or another user. Racism, sexism and other forms of discrimination will not be tolerated.

  • Use standard writing style. Include punctuation and upper and lower cases. Comments that are written in all caps and contain excessive use of symbols will be removed.
  • NOTE: Spam and/or promotional messages and comments containing links will be removed. Phone numbers, email addresses, links to personal or business websites, Skype/Telegram/WhatsApp etc. addresses (including links to groups) will also be removed; self-promotional material or business-related solicitations or PR (ie, contact me for signals/advice etc.), and/or any other comment that contains personal contact specifcs or advertising will be removed as well. In addition, any of the above-mentioned violations may result in suspension of your account.
  • Doxxing. We do not allow any sharing of private or personal contact or other information about any individual or organization. This will result in immediate suspension of the commentor and his or her account.
  • Don’t monopolize the conversation. We appreciate passion and conviction, but we also strongly believe in giving everyone a chance to air their point of view. Therefore, in addition to civil interaction, we expect commenters to offer their opinions succinctly and thoughtfully, but not so repeatedly that others are annoyed or offended. If we receive complaints about individuals who take over a thread or forum, we reserve the right to ban them from the site, without recourse.
  • Only English comments will be allowed.
  • Any comment you publish, together with your investing.com profile, will be public on investing.com and may be indexed and available through third party search engines, such as Google.

Perpetrators of spam or abuse will be deleted from the site and prohibited from future registration at Investing.com’s discretion.

Write your thoughts here
 
Are you sure you want to delete this chart?
 
Post
Post also to:
 
Replace the attached chart with a new chart ?
1000
Your ability to comment is currently suspended due to negative user reports. Your status will be reviewed by our moderators.
Please wait a minute before you try to comment again.
Thanks for your comment. Please note that all comments are pending until approved by our moderators. It may therefore take some time before it appears on our website.
 
Are you sure you want to delete this chart?
 
Post
 
Replace the attached chart with a new chart ?
1000
Your ability to comment is currently suspended due to negative user reports. Your status will be reviewed by our moderators.
Please wait a minute before you try to comment again.
Add Chart to Comment
Confirm Block

Are you sure you want to block %USER_NAME%?

By doing so, you and %USER_NAME% will not be able to see any of each other's Investing.com's posts.

%USER_NAME% was successfully added to your Block List

Since you’ve just unblocked this person, you must wait 48 hours before renewing the block.

Report this comment

I feel that this comment is:

Comment flagged

Thank You!

Your report has been sent to our moderators for review
Continue with Google
or
Sign up with Email