Get 40% Off
🤯 Perficient is up a mind-blowing 53%. Our ProPicks AI saw the buying opportunity in March.Read full update

What Multiple Should We Give China’s GDP Growth?

Published 05/19/2015, 08:40 AM
Updated 07/09/2023, 06:31 AM

Last week, Derek Scissors, a think tank analysts at the American Enterprise Institute, published an article in which he referred to an October, 2014, study by Credit Suisse that attempts to measure total household wealth by region and by country. Scissors argues that in the interminable debate about whether or not China will overtake the US as the world’s largest economy, it is widely assumed that there is only one correct way to decide the answer, and that is by comparing the GDP’s of the two countries.

Some people argue that nominal GDP at the current exchange rate is the appropriate measure, whereas others prefer the to use PPP-adjusted GDP, but there is no reason, Scissors points out, that either of these in fact are the appropriate comparisons:

There is a debate over which country has the world’s largest economy. One side cites gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity and puts China on top, while various other indicators show the United States ahead. The claims are used to gauge China’s importance, highlight Sino-American competition, and sometimes identify China as a threat.

What is almost never in dispute is that China is rising economically relative to the United States. If China is not ahead yet, it is said, the day is coming when it will be. However, at least one vital indicator casts doubt on that thesis: national wealth. From the beginning of 2008 through the middle of 2014, China may have lost ground to the United States in total wealth.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

As Scissors points out, “Credit Suisse put net private American wealth at $42.9 trillion, compared to $4.7 trillion for China: a ratio of more than 9:1”, meaning that the US is 9.1 times wealthier than China. However their GDP ratios are very different. A quick check shows that at the end of 2014, China reported GDP of $9.18 trillion, whereas the US reported $16.77 trillion, so that US GDP is 1.8 times China’s GDP.

This might at first seem strange. A country’s GDP is supposed to measure the amount of wealth created during the period measured, and is often thought of as analogous to the earnings generated by a business. I am not sure exactly what the Credit Suisse estimates of total household wealth represent, but if we think of them as being equal, or at least proportional to, the total market value of each economy’s assets and of their ability, combined with the labor of American or Chinese people, to produce goods and services, it seems that every dollar of American income is 5.0 times as valuable as every dollar of Chinese income. To put it in stock market terms, the US P/E multiple is five times the Chinese P/E multiple.

Is that plausible? Yes it is, although I make no claim about the accuracy of the ratio. Although I don’t find the debate about whether the Chinese economy will overtake that of the US, and if so, when, especially interesting or even intelligent, I do think the question about the relative economic value of the two countries is interesting because it illuminates quite a lot about both the Chinese economy and about how we should be thinking about economic growth.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

But before I explain why a higher US “multiple” can easily be justified, let me turn back to the question of GDP. A country’s gross domestic product, or GDP, is the sum of the value of all the goods and services produced during the GDP period. The OECD defines it, perhaps not as elegantly, as:

“an aggregate measure of production equal to the sum of the gross values added of all resident, institutional units engaged in production (plus any taxes, and minus any subsidies, on products not included in the value of their outputs).”

What good is GDP?

GDP, as we all know, is intended to measure economic wealth creation during a particular period. But, as we also all know, it doesn’t do this very accurately.

Simon Kuznets, the person who is generally credited with having “invented” GDP, in a 1934 report to the US Congress, knew this and was fairly consistent in warning about its weaknesses. The problem with GDP is that there are many things included in GDP calculations – some people propose that these include military expenditures, or brokerage fees – that don’t reflect any real change in the ability of the economy to produce goods and services, whereas other things that do, are often not part of GDP. The most typical examples are things we call positive or negative externalities.

For example, while there may well be positive economic value in creating chemicals and dumping the effluvium in a nearby river, if we ignore the economic costs associated with polluting a river, which may include lower future returns on farming and fishing, and higher future health care costs, and less “pleasure” for future hikers, boaters, and nature lovers, then the “real” economic value of producing the chemicals is likely to be lower than its contribution to GDP.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

What’s more, for something to be part of GDP it has to be part of the recorded cash economy. Prostitutes certainly provide a highly valued service, and an argument can be made that drug dealers do too, at least in a way analogous to bartenders, but they are rarely included in GDP figures. Babysitting provided by an agency is part of GDP, but if a neighbor or relatives do it, it is not part of GDP.

I also want to mention something that is rarely given enough credit as adding to household consumption, certainly to my consumption, but this is the enormous value I get out of Google’s search function, which I am sure vastly exceeds whatever contribution Google adds to GDP. Maybe not everyone is as ecstatic as I am about the fact that I can sit in my office and easily access vast amounts of information, references, and data, but if this were taken away from me it would impoverish me far more than losing a car, or most of my wardrobe.

There is no question that GDP, in other words, does not measure what we usually think it measures, but this doesn’t make GDP a useless number. There are two reasons why it makes sense to invest the time and effort into calculating GDP. First, as long as we constantly remind ourselves of the errors implicit in calculating GDP, and try to correct for them, GDP can give us a rough proxy for total value creation. The second reason is, in my mind, much more important. GDP can be a very useful tool for making comparisons between economies, or between time periods.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

In fact this is one of the main uses of GDP, and it can be very accurate, but its usefulness depends crucially on a condition that is very easy to specify, and yet is so poorly understood and so often violated by economists, that it is frankly a little shocking. There can be failures in the ability of the GDP calculation to capture real value creation, but as long as the failures are consistent, and biased in the same direction, the comparisons are still useful and can be extremely precise and accurate. For example the errors in the calculation of US GDP in 2013 are probably consistent with the errors in the calculation of US GDP in 2014, so that the ratio of 2014’s GDP to 2013’s GDP, which we call the GDP growth rate, is probably extremely close to the real growth in the value of the US economy.

Similarly the GDPs of Canada and the UK are probably constructed incorrectly in ways fairly consistent with that of the US. When I say that at the end of 2014 the US economy was 9.1 times the size of the Canadian economy and 7.4 times the size of the British economy, according to their reported GDPs, we can be reasonably confident that the truth is not too far from that number.

What can you measure with a broken scale?

There is one way that GDP between countries can be distorted, and that is because GDP comparisons are made according to current exchange rates, and of course these vary constantly in real terms. It may turn out that once you adjust for cost, the standard of living in the US may actually imply that the US economy is more, or less, than 9.1 tikes the Canadian economy or 7.4 times the British economy.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

There is a way to correct for this, and that is to adjust the British and Canadian GDP numbers on a purchasing power parity (PPP) basis, so that price difference caused by fluctuations in the real value of the currencies of the three countries is eliminated. This isn’t necessarily easy unless Canadians, English and American households divide their purchases among various goods and service in exactly the same proportions, but it is possible to do a reasonable approximation.

It may now sound like I am belaboring the point unnecessarily with my next metaphor, but there is a reason for this, so please bear with me. I want to make an extremely important point, one which I have made before, and while engineers, mathematicians and bond traders find it annoying that I would even bother making such an obvious point again, economists have so much trouble understanding it, and through them journalists, that I am going to try again to explain.

We often hear that the real way to compare two economies is not on the basis of reported GDP but rather on the basis of the PPP-adjusted GDP. In the article I cited above, for example, Derek Scissors notes that in the debate over whether China or the US is the world’s biggest economy, “one side cites gross domestic product adjusted for purchasing power parity and puts China on top.” In another article he explains why he dismisses the PPP-adjusted GDP calculation, and while his reasons are correct, I think he misses the main and most obvious point.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

Let’s assume I had a broken scale at home that caused the recorded weight of anyone who used it to be consistently higher than his real weight. This would be annoying, but the scale would still be good for two things. First, and most obviously, if I weigh myself every day, I will get a fairly accurate record of the percentage change in my weight on a daily basis, and although I might not know what I really weigh, if all I care about is how well I am managing my weight, the broken scale is as good as an accurate one. This is the equivalent of comparing a country’s GDP growth from one period to the next.

The second thing I can do is compare my weight with that of my friend, who also uses my inaccurate scale, which perhaps we do every New year’s day and publish on my blog. This allows our friends to compare our progress and make jokes at our expense. This progress, or lack of progress, is real. If we do it one New Year’s day, for example, and he turns out to weigh 10% more than I do on my inaccurate scale, it’s a pretty safe bet that he also weighed 10% more than I did in reality, and our friends can make fun of him for weighing more than me. This, of course, is analogous to comparing US GDP with that of the UK or Canada. The real numbers may be inaccurate, but the comparisons are valid.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

But what happens if we always weigh ourselves in the morning after getting out of bed, whereas this year my friend was away from home traveling, and by the time he was able to come to my home to weigh himself it was evening and he had already eaten dinner, when he was likely to be heavier than he would have been in the morning. In that case the comparison between us will have been distorted, in my favor.

There is however a way to fix it. I can ask him to weigh himself in the morning and in the evening over several days, and to average the difference, and then I can use this average to adjust the weight he recorded on that New Year’s day. This adjustment isn’t perfect, but we can all agree that it is a useful adjustment because it gives us a much more accurate measure of our weight difference on that New Year’s day. This adjustment, of course, is analogous to the PPP adjustment – it isn’t perfect, but it certainly improves the accuracy of the comparison.

But let’s say, for some weird reason, I have a second friend with whom I engage in the same ritual. The problem is that this second friend has his own scale, which is also inaccurate, but it is not at all inaccurate in the same way mine is. Because we live so far apart, we have never been able to figure out what the difference is, but we just know that the two scales are inaccurate in totally inconsistent ways.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

It should be pretty obvious that while this second friend can use his scale to measure how well he is managing his weight, any comparison between his recorded weight and mine is pretty much a useless exercise. We know how he is doing on a year-to-year basis, and we know how I am doing, but if we wanted to find out which year it was that we both weighed exactly the same, we wouldn’t be able to tell.

My second friend, however, isn’t terrible smart. If one New Year’s day, he also weighed himself in the evening, and then went through the adjustment process, it would be absurd if he then published the adjusted number and said that this adjustment made the comparison between us much more accurate. Why? Because the adjustment would be random. If his scale recorded higher weights than mine, and the difference was greater than the adjustment, then he is right to say that the adjustment improved accuracy, but this is just by chance. If his scale record lower numbers than mine, or if it records numbers that are higher by less than half of the adjustment, his adjustment actually makes the comparison worse.

Damned PPP again

If everyone understood that the weight comparisons between me and my second friend are inaccurate, and my second friend went through the adjustment process as a joke which everyone understood to be a joke, it wouldn’t matter much, but if when they heard about the adjustment, they took the comparisons seriously because they were told that this adjustment represented a real improvement, I would probably find the whole thing even funnier.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

So what am I talking about – is there really anything analogous to such an absurd story? Unfortunately there is. It is the comparison between the US GDP and China’s GDP on a PPP-adjusted basis. When the World Bank announced China’s PPP-adjusted GDP, it turned out that they were much larger than expected and implied that on a PPP basis China would overtake the US economically much earlier than expected. I posted a blog entry explaining what I though was quite obvious, that because China’s GDP was constructed differently than that of the US, direct comparisons between the two were not terribly useful. It wads downright foolish, however, to make PPP adjustments and imply that what was in effect a completely random change in comparability somehow improved the quality if the comparison.

Some people interpreted this to mean that I had said China used a different set of rules to compile its GDP, but this is not at all what I meant. My point was only that because these two economies were so different, not least because of the enormous role the government played, especially in the financial system, and most especially in the widespread perception of moral hazard, it was inevitable that the many ways in which US GDP was miscalculated would differ significantly from the many ways in which China’s GDP was miscalculated, so that the differences would involve a completely different set of biases between reported GDP and what we might call the “real” value of goods and services produced. In that case any kind of “adjustment” that did not specifically eliminate all the differences in bias, especially a PPP adjustment, would as likely make comparability worse as it would make it better.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

I assumed that it had to be obvious that institutional difference were so great between the two that their biases would render GDP numbers incomparable, but just in case, I mentioned the most glaringly obvious such difference, which was the very different ways in which the two countries recorded the impact of loans made to projects that did not generate enough increases in productivity to justify the investment. Because these were far more likely to be written down in the US than in China, and because most economists agree that the difference is a very large number in GDP terms, the failure to recognize bad loans in China is by itself more than enough to invalidate any PPP adjustment.

When a friend of mine sent me an article from Bloomberg with the title “Bad Math Makes China’s GDP No. 1”, and I discovered that I was the perpetrator of this bad math, was a little surprised, because frankly when I try to do economics, math is not the part that I usually get wrong. Logically speaking, it seemed that there were only two ways the author of the article, Noah Smith, might prove me to be mistaken. One way was to prove that GDP calculations are actually always very accurate measures of real value creation, and the second was to prove that when Chinese banks lend money to projects whose economic value is less than the cost of the investment, they are not less likely to write down the losses than US banks.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

Is an obsession with accuracy unhealthy for the economics establishment?

My math turned out to be bad math for reasons that were totally unexpected. His argument, if I understand it, is that I am asking economists to give up the way they account for GDP. Actually I wasn’t doing any such thing. All I was doing was asking analysts to recognize that accounting rules are attempts to approximate reality, and some times they do so reasonably well, but when they clearly do not, we should be bale to recognize that the output they produce is useless, and so we should ignore it.

Smith writes:

There are plenty of doubts surrounding the Chinese figures, of course. The latest price survey might be just as inaccurate as the earlier ones. Chinese provincial gross domestic product figures are notoriously overstated by job-seeking officials. And the calculation the IMF uses to adjust for price differences, called purchasing power parity, contains a lot of assumptions — using market exchange rates, the U.S. still has the biggest economy.

So when I clicked on a Quartz article entitled “Nope, China’s economy hasn’t yet surpassed America’s,” I expected to see these concerns highlighted. Instead, what I found was that the usually reliable and perspicacious China-watcher Gwynn Guilford had bought into a dodgy theory being promulgated by the renowned Beijing University professor Michael Pettis.

Pettis’s theory, in a nutshell, is that bad investments shouldn’t be counted in GDP… What Pettis is suggesting is that we change the whole way we measure GDP. He wants us to use the discounted present value of assets — in other words, a guess about the far future — as our GDP measure. In other words, he thinks true GDP ought to be a measure of wealth creation rather than a measure of current production.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

We must resist that urge. If economists start trying to subtract perceived malinvestment from GDP, then estimates of GDP will vary wildly from economists to economist, based on how big each one thinks the bubble is. For example, suppose it’s 2007 and I think most of the houses that are being built will eventually be occupied, but you believe that most of them will stand empty and eventually be demolished. If we do what Pettis recommends and subtract our subjective estimates of the percentage of future unused housing from GDP, then you and I will come up with two different GDP numbers!

The friend who sent me the article is a mathematician who is interested in economics, and he was a little too delighted with the article because he knew how frustrated I get by how little intuition most economists seem to have for mathematics, even as they grant mathematically formulated statements with such reverence. He knows I get especially worked up when economists use models whose implicit underlying assumptions are ignored or misunderstood, and this was such a case, here is what he said:

This guy says you’re wrong, not because your sacred implicit assumption remianed intact [i.e. the assumption that biases must be broadly consistent for GDP to be comparable], and not even because Chinese banks didn’t make bad loans (that’s what I expected him to say). You are wrong because China followed the accounting rules in calculating GDP, and if you start questioning the rules you’ll make it impossible to do economics.

He’s right, you know. If you start running around sacrificing precision just because of an unhealthy obsession with accuracy, no one is going to be able to get their work published. Maybe if China wrote down its bad debt, its GDP number would be totally different. Well great, and if they did, you could have a whole different set of GDP numbers to play with, and everyone would be happy. But they didn’t. So deal with it.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

Actually I don’t think Smith understood that I wasn’t saying anything quite so heretical as he thinks. I wasn’t arguing that because GDP is “wrong”, it is therefore useless and should be jettisoned altogether. I was only making what should have been a very obvious mathematical point, and that is that without dismantling the whole structure of economics we could still recognize when certain numbers are useless, and we should understand that the PPP adjustment for China is useless. Smith accepts that are many reasons to question the PPP adjustment, some of which he notes in the first paragraph, and he thinks these are legitimate reason.

They certainly are legitimate reasons, but they are also quite minor. The massive discrepancy in the ability to compare the reported GDPs of China and the US, however, is not at all a minor reason for treating the PPP adjustment as a useless exercise. When I explain this to mathematicians, engineers, or bond traders, they roll their eyes at the obviousness of it all, but this is why I put together the little story about inaccurate scales, which is not a story about why we should throw all our scales away but rather a story about how they can sometimes be useful and how sometimes they cannot. It may seem silly, but so are the constant references to the implications of China’s PPP adjustment, so one way or the other we’re stuck with silliness.

National P/E ratios

But I started this essay out by saying I wanted to discuss a number of reasons that might explain why the US economy would be valued at a higher “multiple” than the Chinese. Of course if the “earnings” part of the P/E multiple is calculated in a different ways, as GDP for China and the US clearly is, that is easily part of the explanation, but there are a few other points I thought worth mentioning.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

1. The difference in the discount rate obviously matters tremendously. In financial terms, the fact that the US is more diversified and less volatile means pretty automatically that its income should be discounted at a lower rate, and so every unit of annual American wealth creation should be more valuable than the same unit of annual Chinese wealth creation. One big problem here might be in determining expected volatility. Historical volatility is probably a useful proxy for expected volatility in the US case, but not in China for at least three important reasons.

2. First, many analysts dispute the veracity of Chinese GDP data and also claim that reported GDP tends to smooth out fluctuations. While the former claim hasn’t been proven to be true over the long term, at least as far I can tell, the latter is almost certainly true. I have seen many studies that try to provide alternative measures of GDP, and while they disagree on whether or not GDP is overstated over the long term, they all agree on the smoothing of data. There also seems to be a consensus, which is consistent with both claims, that growth in the past two quarters has been overstated.

3. Second, a country’s balance sheet structure can systematically exacerbate or dissipate volatility, and I showed in my 2001 book, The Volatility Machine, that developing countries tend to design highly inverted balance sheets for a number of reasons (Hausmann’s “original sin” being among the more obvious). This creates high levels of pro-cyclicality that boost reported growth above the “natural” growth during the expansion phase, but of course the same reflexive mechanisms do the opposite during the adjustment phase.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

Economists don’t often seem to understand this mechanism unless they are also finance specialists, and in most previous cases, when “miracle” growth turned out to be largely based on excess leverage and the reflexive relationship between the two, while they were often at first surprised by the unexpectedly strong growth, they nearly always eventually attributed it to unique but sustainable circumstances, and so over time simply adjusted upwards their estimates of potential growth to account for the higher growth numbers. It is probably worth noting that in nearly every case, the unique but sustainable circumstance that most economists believed explained the surprisingly high growth turned out to be the implementation of a new kind of growth model, or, and the two were usually intertwined, a new way of economic thinking by a highly sophisticated policymaking elite (this new form of economic thinking usually belongs to that most flexible of schools, “non-Western” economics.

Investors have usually done a better job of recognizing the reflexive relationship between growth and credit, although in the end the this-time-is-different story ends up enchanting investors anyway, whether the reason for thinking that this time is different is a new economic growth model that create a growth miracle, or new technology that promises to create enough improvement in productivity to justify any stock market price, or a new kind of financial organization that promises all but to eliminate financial risk. I think most bubbles are set off in one of these three forms, and I think it was Charles Kindelberger who pointed out that the story explaining the bubble is nearly always well-justified during the early stages, sometimes powerfully so, and this makes subsequent skepticism all the harder.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

In China’s case, if you believe this model applies, the combination of the Japanese and civil wars, followed by three decades of questionable policy-making, probably left the country seriously under-invested both in manufacturing capacity and in infrastructure. For that reason Deng’s reforms in the 1980s and the subsequent early stages of the investment model were probably periods of such spectacular real growth, and of real increases in wealth, that it seemed even easier than in previous cases to reject any explanation which pointed to unsustainable increases in debt as an important source of continued growth.

4. And third, of course, is that the discount rate must include a premium for “gapping risk”, by which I mean the risk of an unexpected and sharp drop. If investors believe that a developing country like China is more prone to downward shocks than an advanced country like the US, or if investors believe that China’s autocratic political system is more likely to break down than the US democracy, or if investors think a more centralized economic system with a few very large players that excercise disproportionate control, like in China, is more vulnerable to “systems breakdown” then the more decentralized US economy (and there are many other kinds of gapping that can occur), than even if none of these have happened in the past, they must raise their discount rates anyway.

As an aside, I worry that in the last of my three examples, China may not be at as big a relative disadvantage as we think. The increasing concentration of financial power in the US to a limited number of institutions cannot help but increase gapping risk in the US economy. As long as investors believe there is a greater chance of gapping in China, the impact on the discount rate can be very high, but Americans should recognize that when sectors of the economy are heavily concentrated, there may be efficiency gains (although I suspect that these are vastly overestimated), this concentration necessarily creates much stronger institutional constraints that prevents the economy from its tendency to rebalance automatically, and as this allows imbalances to deepen, it is worth remembering that the deeper the imbalance, the greater the risk of a disruptive adjustment – which is another form of gapping risk.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

All of this suggests that the rate at which we discount US GDP is likely to be much lower than the Chinese discount rate, but we cannot forget that because China is expected to grow more quickly, this too should be factored into the discount rate, to China’s benefit (i.e. it reduces the Chinese discount rate). Of course both GDP growth rates are uncertain, let alone the expected differential, and there is too great a dispute among us about expected Chinese growth rates to even begin to address it, but if we are trying to explain valuation differences, this has to be part of it.

5. Finally I would argue that all of the above implicitly assumes that in either case GDP is a good proxy for wealth creation. Of course it isn’t. As I discussed above, there is far too much economic activity included in the GDP calculation, or excluded from it, whose real impact on wealth creation is not the same as its impact on GDP growth, for it to be an accurate measure of wealth creation. But it might be a reasonable enough proxy, in which case the real value of GDP to economists is not the reported number itself but rather its usefulness in making comparisons.

For the reasons I discussed above, I don’t think we can compare the GDPs of the US and China with much of confidence. I would propose at least two very different biases that might explain part of the higher valuation of US wealth. The first has to do with externalities that are not included in GDP calculations. If the US has higher positive or lower negative externalities, this should show up in the form of a higher wealth valuation. It is easy to come up with lists of externalities in favor of one or the other, but I would argue that among higher positive externalities in the US, two big ones might be: a)the value of education, and b)the institutional framework behind the astonishing creativity in the US. I have more broadly referred to the latter as “social capital”, and have discussed several times what I mean by it, perhaps most extensively in a June 10, 2013 essay.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

Some might argue that the latter is already included in the US GDP numbers, but if you think that the US is more likely to benefit from the unexpected creation of an important productivity-enhancing technology, this is the equivalent of embedding a kind of option in total value of US wealth, and these options can be quite valuable. On the flip side I would argue that among higher negative externalities in China it is hard not to think immediately of environmental degradation, which leaves China poorer in a way not measured in GDP. I should also mention China’s huge water problem, which is widely recognized and, by implying significant future costs, their properly discounted value should reduce China’s wealth without showing up in today’s GDP numbers. Of course water is becoming a problem not just for China, and I understand that in California it is starting to become a severe constrant on the agriculture sector, but I think the sheer extent of China’s water problem may be unprecedented.

6. And finally, the second of the obvious and large GDP biases that makes it nearly pointless to compare the two GDP numbers — in spite of all the excitement generated by these comparisons, especially the most foolish of them all, the PPP adjusted comparison — is the treatment of debt. I’ve already discussed why this is such an important issue in invalidating GDP comparisons, but to summarize, if you believe that the US financial system is far more likely than that of China to write down loans that have funded projects whose returns do not justify their costs, then you also must believe that real economic losses which would have reduced the amount of GDP calculated for the US did not reduce the amount of GDP calculated for China, even though the real economic impact would have been identical. If this is the case US GDP is relatively understated by the amount of the bad loans that are unrecognized in China but would have been recognized in the US, and some estimates of this number are extremely high.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

Multiples and growth differentials

There is a lot more to say, but the much greater disparity in US and Chinese wealth than the disparity in their GDP growth numbers might not be hard to justify. I have ignored reasons that might justify lower discount rates or higher GDP adjustments mainly because the purpose of this essay is to explain why the US multiple is so much higher than China’s, and of course these reasons exist, but I think whatever the correct ratio should be, there is no question that advanced economies always justify higher multiples than developing economies because they tend to be economically more diversified and politically more stable, and they usually have institutions, including a clearer legal and regulatory framework, a more sophisticated capital allocation process, less rigid financial systems, and smaller state sectors (which makes smooth adjustment, one of the most valuable and undervalued components of long-term growth, more likely).

In the case of China and the US, I would add two points. First, although it should be clear that neither GDP is “correct” as a true measure of wealth creation, I think there are good reasons to argue that the difference in real wealth creation might be greater than the difference in GDP – US wealth creation is a higher relative to US GDP than China’s wealth creation is relative to China’s GDP – and it is this adjusted GDP, representing real wealth creation, whose value must be discounted to determine the economic “wealth” of each country. However, depending on how much faster China’s “adjusted” GDP grows relative to that of the US “adjusted” GDP growth, this difference must show up in China’s favor in the discount rate.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

In fact the growth differential must be among the most important factors in determining the relative “multiples”, and it is nominal growth, not real, that matters. There is, of course, great deal of skepticism about China’s 7% real GDP growth rate, but we should remember that in the first quarter, nominal GDP growth was much lower, 5.8%. In the past tow days there have been a number of announcements that suggest that Beijing is worried enough about the growth slowdown that it may unleash a new wave of infrastructure-based spending. If this is true, it should cause GDP growth to pick up, and so widen the growth differential between China and the US, but unfortunately this does not mean that there should be a corresponding drop in the rate at which we discount Chinese growth. This depends on whether we believe that additional infrastructure spending will increase the country’s potential growth rate, or that it will simply increase economic activity at the expense of higher debt. If we assume that Beijing has been reluctant to do this in the past, and is only doing so in response to weaker expected growth numbers, it would suggest the latter explanation, which implies a higher, not a lower, discount rate.

Second, ignoring the factor that represents the growth differential, there is absolutely no way to justify similar discount rates for the two economies. Every dollar in the adjusted US GDP must be more valuable than every dollar in China’s adjusted GDP, because US wealth creation almost certainly must be discounted at a lower rate. But how much lower? However you measure it, it seems to me that the appropriate US discount rate should be substantially lower, but one controversial component is likely to justify by far the biggest part of the difference. This is the impact of balance sheet inversion on the discount rate.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

If you believe that a very large component of China’s GDP growth is explained by the pro-cyclicality of balance sheet distortions, or if you accept the validity of CAPM as the right way to value higher expected growth based only on higher leverage, then you have to raise the Chinese discount rate to eliminate altogether the value of this additional growth.

I plan to write about this balance sheet issue a lot more elsewhere, including in an upcoming review of Nick Lardy’s excellent recent book, Markets over Mao: The Rise of Private Business in China. I believe the review will be published in the July 2014 issue of Asia Policy, the journal of the The National Bureau of Asian Research, and will feature short review essays by five to six experts, followed by a response from Lardy. The point of my review is to explain why what seems like a paradox is in fact easily explained. I don’t think anyone has an understanding of the fundamental nature of China’s economy, its political economy institutional structure, and the evolution of its economy since the beginning of the reforms, better than Lardy.

He is also very careful in his work and not prone to excess. His book explains the evolution of China’s transformation from a state dominated economy to one in which the private sector is the engine of employment and productivity growth. This explanation leads him inexorably to the conclusion that China will continue to grow rapidly during the rest of President Xi’s administration, which is expected to end in 2023, and he forecasts growth rates as high as 8%.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

I have read his book and agree with nearly all of it, or at least I am not smart enough or knowledgeable enough to show why he is wrong. And yet just as inexorably I conclude that the risks are substantial, and that if China is able to grow on average at half that rate, Xi will deserve to be widely acknowledged as having pulled of an extraordinary feat.

Whatever the topic, I always see balance sheets

How can the same set of facts lead to such widely differing forecasts. The reasons, I will argue, have to do with how we evaluate the impact of the two sides of and economic entity’s balance sheet on its growth. Lardy, I will argue, and like the vast majority of economists, thinks of growth as largely a function of how productively the assets side of the balance sheet is managed, and this is true of all economic entities, ranging from businesses to countries to the global economy. The liability structure is not irrelevant, according to this view, but it matters mainly because too much debt creates the risk of a debt crisis, or can undermine confidence. Otherwise it is functionally irrelevant.

For me, and this view is not unanimous but much more widely held among finance specialists, this “asset side” view of growth is only true under specific conditions, but once debt levels are high enough, or the liability structure is distorted in ways that can be specified fairly accurately, debt moves increasingly towards functional centrality. They do so in two important ways. First – and although there have been scattered references throughout the literature about this process, there has been no attempt, as far as I know, to describe this process systematically – distorted liability structures, or what I call “inverted balance sheets in my book, The Volatility Machine, can create highly pro-cyclical and self-reinforcing mechanism, especially through the financial sector, that systematically exacerbate expansion and contraction phases in the economy. These can be so powerful that, especially in developing economies, they can turn rapid growth into growth “miracles”, but they also can cause the subsequent adjustment into a surprisingly difficult period of stagnation.

3rd party Ad. Not an offer or recommendation by Investing.com. See disclosure here or remove ads .

The second important way debt can become functionally central to growth emerges from the well-known and much studied process that in finance theory is referred to as financial distress. As regular readers of my blog know, I have think of the trigger not as the rising probability of default but rather rising uncertainty about how debt will be resolved, which of course necessarily includes but is not limited by the rising probability of default. I have redefined it in this way because while financial distress is almost always assumed to be something to which only businesses are vulnerable, in fact the theory is applicable to the full range of economic entities, for which in some cases default is irrelevant.

There is a lot more to say, and I hope to develop these ideas more fully in the next few years, but for now I think the discussion Scissors triggered with his essay can be a useful way to think about the Chinese economy – not so much because we need a way to decide which eco9bomy is the world’s largest, but rather because the value we place on current and future growth tells us a lot about the quality of that growth. It also helps has important policy implications. Thing about the reform process can be helpfully refined by understanding the value of different kinds of growth.

Latest comments

Risk Disclosure: Trading in financial instruments and/or cryptocurrencies involves high risks including the risk of losing some, or all, of your investment amount, and may not be suitable for all investors. Prices of cryptocurrencies are extremely volatile and may be affected by external factors such as financial, regulatory or political events. Trading on margin increases the financial risks.
Before deciding to trade in financial instrument or cryptocurrencies you should be fully informed of the risks and costs associated with trading the financial markets, carefully consider your investment objectives, level of experience, and risk appetite, and seek professional advice where needed.
Fusion Media would like to remind you that the data contained in this website is not necessarily real-time nor accurate. The data and prices on the website are not necessarily provided by any market or exchange, but may be provided by market makers, and so prices may not be accurate and may differ from the actual price at any given market, meaning prices are indicative and not appropriate for trading purposes. Fusion Media and any provider of the data contained in this website will not accept liability for any loss or damage as a result of your trading, or your reliance on the information contained within this website.
It is prohibited to use, store, reproduce, display, modify, transmit or distribute the data contained in this website without the explicit prior written permission of Fusion Media and/or the data provider. All intellectual property rights are reserved by the providers and/or the exchange providing the data contained in this website.
Fusion Media may be compensated by the advertisers that appear on the website, based on your interaction with the advertisements or advertisers.
© 2007-2024 - Fusion Media Limited. All Rights Reserved.