Breaking News
Get 40% Off 0
☕ Buy the dip? After losing 17%, Starbucks sees an estimated 20% upside. See the top Undervalued stocks! Unlock list

Why institutions matter (more than ever)

By Bank of EnglandSep 04, 2013 06:33PM ET
 
Speech given by
Andrew G Haldane, Executive Director, Financial Stability

Centre for Research on Socio-Cultural Change (CRESC) Annual Conference, School of
Oriental and African Studies, London
4 September 2013

The views are not necessarily those of the Bank of England or the Financial Policy Committee. I
would like to thank James Benford, Edd Denbee, Jack Grigg, Bob Hills, John Hooley, Sujit Kapadia,
David Learmonth, Varun Paul, Fiona Robinson, Paul Tucker and Iain de Weymarn for comments and
contributions.



It is a great pleasure to be speaking at this year’s CRESC annual conference. It is particularly poignant, in the week of Ronald Coase’s death, to be discussing “Why Institutions Matter”. This is belatedly becoming
conventional economic wisdom. Yet I wish to argue not just that institutions matter, but that the forces shaping today’s great global systems mean they matter more today than ever previously.

It is a great pleasure to be speaking at this year’s CRESC annual conference. It is particularly poignant, in
the week of Ronald Coase’s death, to be discussing “Why Institutions Matter”. This is belatedly becoming
conventional economic wisdom. Yet I wish to argue not just that institutions matter, but that the forces
shaping today’s great global systems mean they matter more today than ever previously.

Take integration. Cross-border flows of resources -people, goods and services, capital – have seen a
remarkable upsurge over the past few decades. Chart 1 plots some measures of cross-border flows of
goods, services and capital – the ratios of world trade and global external assets to world GDP. They exhibit
broadly similar trends: rising in the early part of the 20th century, falling during the interwar years, before
rising rapidly to the present day. They chart the ebb and flow of globalisation.

Over the past 30 years, globalisation has flowed as never before. Trade integration has risen at a rate of
over 1 percentage point per year, international capital integration at a rate of 6 percentage points per year.
Today, the ratio of world trade to GDP is two and a half times its level at the end of the Second World War.
The ratio of global external assets to world GDP is nearly ten times this level. Global integration of goods,
services, money and people is at levels well beyond those seen previously.

The creation and exchange of information has undergone an even more remarkable phase shift. The stock
of information currently available is estimated to be around 1,200 exa-bytes.1 Sufficient, if it were placed on
CDs, to stretch to the moon and back almost three times. Sufficient for every person on the planet to each
have over 300 times more information than was stored in the great library at Alexandria which, 2000 years
ago, housed the sum of all human knowledge (Cukier and Mayer-Schoenberger (2013)).

What is more, almost all of this information is new. Over 90% of it has become available in the past 10
years. Nearly half has become available in the past 3 years. This rate of expansion is unlikely to slow.
Google alone processes 25 million gigabytes of data each day (Devenport et al. (2012)). Wal-Mart is
handling 1 million new transactions every hour. Facebook is home to 40 billion digital photographs which
increase at a rate of 10 million per hour. Looking ahead, the stock of information is forecast to double over
the next 3 years (Cukier and Mayer-Schoenberger (2013)).

On these trends, by 2020 the stock of information will have risen 150-fold since the turn of the century.2 At
that stage, the information created this century will account for over 99% of that ever created. That CD pile

will stretch to the moon and back more than 10 times. Each person alive will have nearly 1500 times more
information than was housed in Alexandria.
will stretch to the moon and back more than 10 times. Each person alive will have nearly 1500 times more
information than was housed in Alexandria.

These remarkable trends in global integration have delivered significant benefits to global wealth and
welfare, providing a large boost to growth (Kose et al. (2006), World Bank (2008)). There is also now
decisive evidence of the IT revolution having materially boosted economy-wide productivity (Jorgenson et al.
(2008)). As more of the economy has become virtual and global, and less physical and local, it is possible
that existing national income methods may, if anything, have understated these gains (Arthur (2009)).

Yet, as recent events attest, rapidly rising integration and information are not costless. They can reshape
and rescale the risks facing social, economic and financial systems. In particular, I wish to argue that the
twin forces of integration and information may have increased the severity of the tail risks facing global
systems, as recently evidenced by the global financial crisis. Insuring against those rising tail risks may call
for a fresh policy response – for example, a strengthening of public policy institutions.

Integration and Systemic Risk

Consider first the relationship between integration and systemic risk. It is well-known that deeper integration
of a network does not have a straightforward impact on its stability. Integration can be a double-edged
sword – and the greater the degree of integration, the sharper this sword. This is sometimes known as the
“robust-yet-fragile” property of connected webs (Watts (2002)).

The intuition is beguilingly simple. Within limits, connectivity acts as a shock-absorber, a risk-spreader.
Links in the system act as a mutual insurance device as risk is distributed and diversified away. That results
in connected networks appearing “robust” to shocks. But when shocks are sufficiently large, the same
connectivity serves as a shock-transmitter. Risk-sharing becomes risk-spreading. Links in the system act as
a mutual incendiary device as risk is amplified across the wider web. Connected networks become “fragile”.

In short, connected networks tend simultaneously to be stable and unstable, calm and turbulent,
robust-yet-fragile. They sit atop a cliff-edge, on one side of which are the sunny uplands of stability, on the
other the stormy lowlands of fragility. The more connected and integrated the system, the more precipitate
this cliff-edge (Acemoglu et al. (2013), Haldane (2009), Gai and Kapadia (2010)).

As we might expect, the distribution of outcomes from such robust-yet-fragile systems are lumpy and
non-normal. Relative to the smooth contours of the bell curve, they generate a clustering of extreme
outcomes as systems tip the wrong side of the cliff edge. The distributions have “fat tails”. In simple terms,
this tells us that catastrophes are much more likely than if God were rolling a dice (Haldane and
Nelson (2012)).



This fat-tailed property has been found in most connected webs on the planet: in natural networks, such as
rainforests and oceans; in physical networks, such as electricity grids and computer networks; in social
networks, such as epidemics and social media sites; and in economic networks, such as trade networks and
interbank payment systems (Newman (2005)). For all of these systems, the abnormal is normal, the
exception the rule, the local global, the tails fat.

This fat-tailed property has been found in most connected webs on the planet: in natural networks, such as
rainforests and oceans; in physical networks, such as electricity grids and computer networks; in social
networks, such as epidemics and social media sites; and in economic networks, such as trade networks and
interbank payment systems (Newman (2005)). For all of these systems, the abnormal is normal, the
exception the rule, the local global, the tails fat.

Robust yet, as subsequent events have shown, also fragile. At the same time financial integration was
calming the waters on shore, it was brewing a storm at sea. The financial system’s tail was fattening. When
that tail wagged in 2008, almost every country on the planet fell off the cliff-edge at an almost identical time.
The world experienced its first-ever truly global financial crisis. This time was different.

Unprecedented levels of financial integration made that so. Over the course of a 30-year period, it had
transformed the global financial system into a tangled cats-cradle, the ultimate robust-yet-fragile web. While
everyone was shocked by the crisis, perhaps no-one should have been surprised by it. If the path of
integration – social, economic, financial – continues skyward, next time will be different for other systems too.

Information and Systemic Risk

Consider next the link between information and systemic risk. Here again the relationship is far from
straightforward. Increased information is generally felt to improve decision-making; it allows us to
re-optimise in response to news. Facebook and Twitter allow us to befriend and defriend, to like and dislike,
in real time. eBay and Amazon allow us to trade instantaneously. Trading platforms allow us to buy and sell
at sub-second speeds. Matchmaking sites allow us to search for jobs and partners in our lunch-break.
People, goods, services and money all now swim in a liquid real-time market.

Yet high-frequency information and decision-making may be neither costless nor harmless. To understand
why, look inside your head. MRI scans now enable us to do just that. What they show is that, neurologically,
humans are schizophrenic by design. The brain is part impatient “doer”, part patient “planner”. Those two
components result in us “Thinking fast and slow” (Kahneman (2011)).

Information prompts a chemical reaction in the impatient part of the brain. This provides the synaptic spark
to re-optimise, to exchange, to transact, to befriend, to change our minds as never before. And change our
minds, quite literally, it has. Some have argued that the information flood may have caused a neurological


rewiring, the like of which followed previous IT revolutions such as the printing press (Carr (2011)). This may
have reduced attention spans, perhaps permanently; it has hardwired myopia.

rewiring, the like of which followed previous IT revolutions such as the printing press (Carr (2011)). This may
have reduced attention spans, perhaps permanently; it has hardwired myopia.

In other words, an information surplus may cause an attention deficit. An attention deficit is likely to lower
the quality of decision-making. For cognitive psychologists, it is a disorder – one whose reported incidence
has sky-rocketed over recent years. If short-term reactions are clouding long-term judgements, the doer
crowding-out the planner, the immediate the important, then more hurry may be generating less speed.

This might be called the “information-rich-yet-attention-poor” property of connected webs. One manifestation
is over-trading – over-trading in friends, partners, jobs, stocks. Perhaps that is why marriage rates have
halved, and divorce rates doubled, in the UK since 1970; why the tenure of global CEOs has halved since
1995; and why holding periods for stocks has more than halved since 1980. For many key decisions,
myopia has been mounting.

It may also have become self-reinforcing – a myopia trap. For addicts, shortened horizons generate a quest
for quick fixes which further shorten horizons in a downward spiral (Coffey et al. (2003)). For gamblers, a
sequence of losses shortens horizons and increases risk-taking (Xiu et al. (2011)). For depression-sufferers,
low confidence in the future becomes self-fulfilling (Alloy and Ahrens (1987)).

Myopia traps affect countries as well as individuals – and their macro-economic costs can be large. For
developing countries, they often materialise as “poverty traps” (Sachs (2005)). That trap is self-sustaining
because poverty leads to under-investment in the human and financial capital that would allow the country to
break free in the future (Banerjee and Duflo (2011)). Low future prospects for growth become self-fulfilling.

Advanced economies are not immune to these problems. An information-rich-attention-poor world will
generate under-investment in physical and human capital, infrastructure, the environment. That will be
self-sustaining if it lowers future prospects or heightens future risks (Davies et al. (2013)). More hurry then
assuredly means less speed. This is not a poverty trap. It is a poverty of attention trap. Policymakers have
recently begun to focus on short-termism, perhaps for that reason (G30 (2012), FSB (2013)).

There is a final twist in this story of the dark side of integration and information. Fat tails and short minds can
combine in uncomfortable ways. Myopia generates under-insurance against future risks, especially tail risks
which seem remote. Yet, courtesy of integration, these tail risks may be on the rise. In other words,
systemic risks may be rising at precisely the time societal insurance against these risks is most needed.



One response would be to turn the tide, reversing the paths of integration and information. Since the crisis,
there have been some signs of just that. Chart 2 shows one measure of global capital market integration
over the past century – the correlation between national saving and investment rates in a set of countries. A
value of one signals financial autarky – countries fully reliant on domestic saving to finance investment. A
value of zero signals perfect financial integration – countries financing local investment globally.

For much of the 20th century, global financial integration, so measured, was very low. In the early 1980s,
after decades of post-war financial liberalisation, this was seen as a “puzzle” (Feldstein and Horioka (1980)).
Yet at precisely that point, the puzzle began to unravel. Correlations between national saving and
investment began falling. By 2007, they had reached zero – bliss point for global capital market integration.

Yet bliss was short-lived. 2007 proved to be a high-water mark. The onset of the financial crisis has resulted
in significant capital market retrenchment as nation states have returned money home, placed regulatory
ring-fences around assets and imposed restrictions on capital movement. Today, global capital market
integration is back to levels last seen in 2000 and is still falling.

This retrenchment reflects nervousness about the dark side of globalisation, its fragility and contagious cost.
And this nervousness is not confined to capital flows; it has affected flows of goods, services and people too.
That is why the World Trade Organisation’s (WTO) latest round of negotiations has been on-going for nearly
12 years. And it is why policy debates about immigration restrictions in a great many advanced economies
are so vexed. These are attempts to turn the tide or at least stem the flood.

The costs of a significant retreat in flows of capital, goods, services and people are difficult to quantify. They
are not, however, difficult to imagine. We need only look back to the aftermath of the First World War for a
case study. Then, trade barriers were erected, capital flows restricted, immigration controls imposed. What
followed was not a halcyon period for the global social, economic and financial order.

Reversing the rising tide of information would be an even more Canute-like task. While the library at
Alexandria succumbed to fire, it is difficult to see the clouds suffering the same fate. Ending quarterly
reporting will not bring an end of quarterly capitalism. The flood of information seems set to continue to rise,
our cognitive in-box overflowing, our brains rewiring.


That begs the question of whether there is another public policy path better able to tackle fat tails and short
minds. There may be. It is both an old path and a new path. Along it lie institutions -“humanly devised
constraints that structure political, economic and social interactions” (North (1991)). So defined, institutions
have long been recognised as key ingredients of stability and growth.

That begs the question of whether there is another public policy path better able to tackle fat tails and short
minds. There may be. It is both an old path and a new path. Along it lie institutions -“humanly devised
constraints that structure political, economic and social interactions” (North (1991)). So defined, institutions
have long been recognised as key ingredients of stability and growth.

In the late 19th century, economists such as Thorsten Veblen went one step further. They saw institutions as
the basic building blocks of economic development (Veblen (1899)). As societies and economies became
more complex, institutions were needed to solve increasingly complex collective action problems. They
helped co-ordinate the actions of individuals to create public goods such as language, money, the rule of
law, even central banks.

After a lull of over half a century, institutional economics has re-emerged with a vengeance. For
Ronald Coase and Douglas North, institutions helped solve information and co-ordination problems within
organisations, communities and societies (Coase (1960), North (1981)). The more complex these
information problems, the more important were institutions as staging posts to efficiency and progress.

For Mancur Olson, institutions could be a bulwark against the power of vested interests (Olson (1982)).
Vocal minorities could block reform which would otherwise benefit the silent majority – for example, through
tougher anti-trust law and tighter regulation. Institutions, arms-length from these vested interests, could
break that reform logjam and thereby act as a growth facilitator.

A common denominator among all of these thinkers, from Smith to Veblen to Coase to North, is that
institutions rise in importance as societies become more complex, integrated and information-rich. Indeed,
by embedding knowledge from the past, and investing in public goods for the future, institutions were
essential prerequisites for continuing progress in such systems.

Recently, those basic insights have been corroborated by historical evidence. Institutional quality has been
found to be a key determinant of economic growth, particularly during financial liberalisation (Kose et al.
(2006)). For Acemoglu and Robinson (2012), institutions play the pivotal role in explaining “Why Nations
Fail”. In an echo of Olson, they distinguish extractive (catering for an elite) and inclusive (catering for
society) regimes, with the first a recipe for economic regress, the latter for progress.

Whether old or new, institutions seem to matter. Their secret lies in solving societal problems of knowledge,
co-ordination and incentives. Institutional memory can help lengthen and strengthen otherwise short and

subjective minds. And institutional investment can help build public goods and flatten otherwise fat tails. In
other words, institutions are the perfect antidote to the dark sides of integration and information.

subjective minds. And institutional investment can help build public goods and flatten otherwise fat tails. In
other words, institutions are the perfect antidote to the dark sides of integration and information.

These features of institutions – memory of the past, investment for the future – are particularly acute when
tackling economic and financial policy problems. Very often, these involve difficult trade-offs between today
and tomorrow: is growth today worth trading-off against higher inflation tomorrow or a greater probability of
crisis the day after tomorrow?

Not only are these choices difficult, but policymakers may have an inbuilt tendency to get them wrong. In
economics, this is often termed the “time consistency” problem (Kydland and Prescott (1977)). The problem
arises when policymakers have incentives to promise good behaviour ex-ante, but then renege on that
promise ex-post. Policymakers are prone to making St Augustinian pledges to be chaste, just not yet. This
is a classic myopia trap.

The roots of this problem are often felt to be political – a desire to court near-term popularity to achieve
re-election. Yet the true roots may be more neurological than political. Experimental evidence shows that
people’s preferences are themselves time-inconsistent or “hyperbolic” (Laibson (1997)). People become
increasingly myopic as payoffs become visible, elections approach, nest eggs near hatching. This is true for
everything from pigeons pecking corn to mothers seeking pain relief during childbirth (Haldane (2010)).

One man’s hyperbolic preferences are another’s policy time-inconsistencies. For example, when setting
monetary policy, there may be a desire to go for growth today at the expense of inflation tomorrow – to seek
the drugs rather than gas and air option. Because people over time build that behaviour into their
expectations, the result may be a permanent upwards inflation bias, the like of which blighted many
advanced economies in the 1970s (Barro and Gordon (1983)).

Over the past 30 years, practical solutions have been sought to this monetary policy myopia problem.
Interestingly, these solutions have often been explicitly institutional. Over that period, monetary policy in a
great many countries has been placed in the hands of central banks operating arms-length from government,
but with an inflation mandate set by government.

The reasons for doing so should be readily familiar from the earlier literature on institutional economics.
Central banks have institutional memory, embedding past knowledge of the costs of inflationary excess. For
example, the Bundesbank’s inflation-aversion is deeply rooted in Germany’s hyperinflationary past. This
memory of the past is crucial for preserving the value of money in the future.


So too is operational independence from government. This helps provide the patience necessary to
safeguard future stability in the value of money – for example, through an inflation target. It leans against the
St Augustinian tendency to dash for growth today at the expense of inflation tomorrow. Today, these
institutional principles for monetary policy are enshrined in the statutes of central banks in all of the major
advanced countries and a growing number of emerging markets.

So too is operational independence from government. This helps provide the patience necessary to
safeguard future stability in the value of money – for example, through an inflation target. It leans against the
St Augustinian tendency to dash for growth today at the expense of inflation tomorrow. Today, these
institutional principles for monetary policy are enshrined in the statutes of central banks in all of the major
advanced countries and a growing number of emerging markets.

First, financial cycles are longer-lived than the typical business cycle. Chart 3 plots a measure of the cycles
in credit and GDP in the UK over the past century (Aikman et al. (2010)). Peak-to-peak, the credit cycle lasts
between 8 and 20 years, the business cycle between 2 and 8 years. The longer duration of credit cycles
increases the chances of policymakers falling prey to disaster myopia. That is why “This time is different”
has so often been the pre-crisis narrative (Reinhart and Rogoff (2009)). In an
“information-rich-yet-attention-poor” world, people in future may be even more prone to such myopia.

Second, the financial cycle exhibits wider fluctuations, and imposes much larger costs, than the typical
business cycle. As Chart 3 shows, the amplitude of the credit cycle is more than twice the business cycle.
The costs of crisis dwarf those of business cycle fluctuations (Claessens et al. (2008), Jorda et al. (2011)).
By making the system “robust-yet-fragile”, financial integration has fattened tails and added to these costs.
This, too, strengthens the case for remedial policy action to avert these tails and their associated costs.

Third, the financial cycle tends to generate stronger constituencies of winners and losers than the business
cycle. This includes asset-owners benefitting from asset price booms, borrowers benefitting from credit
booms or banks benefitting from both. Each is a powerful vested interest. This makes for stronger and more
successful lobbying, making it harder to lean against financial cycles.

A financial boom is, in effect, a generational power struggle. The beneficiaries from an asset boom are
today’s asset-owning older generation. Vocal and voting, they are a powerful coalition. The losers from an
asset boom are today’s younger or future generations who face costlier assets or larger amounts of debt to
repay. Yet they are often neither vocal nor voting. Many will be unborn. They are a weak coalition.

This generational imbalance of power may generate an inherent pressure to expand credit and inflate asset
prices. The financial system may have in-built tendencies to create credit and asset booms, to enable the
transfer of resources from tomorrow to today, from the young and unborn to the old, from the silent to the
vocal. Yet, longer-term, this is another myopia trap. Indeed, as it is effectively a transfer from the pockets of
our children and grandchildren, it is the ultimate deceit.


If regulatory attempts are made to reign in financial excesses, there is a second political-economy problem to
navigate. Regulatory action will tend to focus on staunching the sources of credit, namely the banking
system. But this pits regulators against a powerful, and well-heeled, coalition of potential losers, often
resentful of those removing the party’s punchbowl. Such is the story of the past five (hundred) years.

If regulatory attempts are made to reign in financial excesses, there is a second political-economy problem to
navigate. Regulatory action will tend to focus on staunching the sources of credit, namely the banking
system. But this pits regulators against a powerful, and well-heeled, coalition of potential losers, often
resentful of those removing the party’s punchbowl. Such is the story of the past five (hundred) years.

Institutions and Regulatory Design

The features of the financial system that generate this dilemma are in many respects familiar: a shortage of
embedded knowledge of the past, an absence of co-ordinating action for the future, the power of vested
interests wishing to trade off the future for the present. That suggests institutional reform could be a key
ingredient when reducing financial time-consistency problems. What institutional features are likely to be
most important in safeguarding financial stability?

First, financial crises underscore the importance of placing responsibility for their avoidance in the hands of a
policymaker with institutional memory. This reduces the risk of disaster myopia, of ignoring worrying dots on
distant horizons, of being “information-rich-yet-attention-poor”, of forgetting fat tails. To misquote
Mark Twain, although crises do not repeat themselves they do rhyme. Long-lived institutions are likely to be
better able to recall those ancient rhymes.

Second, financial policymakers should ideally be arms-length from the political process – for example,
operationally independent for regulatory tools. This reduces the temptation to trade off an asset boom today
for a bust tomorrow. It helps delivers greater investment in future financial stability and greater insurance
against fat tail risk. It helps avoid the ultimate deceit of mortgaging the unborn.

Third, financial policy needs to have a system-wide focus. In the jargon, it needs to be macro-prudential in
nature (Crockett (2000)). That is essential in an integrated “robust-yet-fragile” world where crises, when they
come, are fat-tailed and global. Because it is system-wide, macro-prudential regulation may also help muffle
the siren voices of vested interests, increasing the chances of an inclusive, rather than extractive, regime.

In large measure, these institutional characteristics are reflected in the UK’s new regulatory arrangements.
These came into place with the passage of the Financial Services Act (2012). Under this framework,
responsibility for prudential policy falls to the Bank of England. It is split between the Prudential Regulation


The new institutional framework for UK financial policy in many respects mirrors that for UK monetary policy.
As with monetary policy, both the FPC and PRA have operational independence when setting certain
prudential instruments. As with monetary policy, both operate subject to statutory objectives and remits set
by Parliament. And as with monetary policy, each is subject to rigorous accountability mechanisms enforced
by Parliament. Both FPC and MPC have instrument, but not goal, independence.

These institutional features have attractions as a response to the time-consistency dilemma which faces
financial policymakers. The Bank of England is an institution with around 320 years of history. Financial
crises have pock-marked its history. This ought to provide the Bank with the institutional memory necessary
to make sense of dots on distant horizons, to diagnose emerging obesity in the financial system’s tails, to
conscientiously object to next time appearing different.

The primary objective of the FPC is to preserve the resilience of the financial system and, subject to that, to
support the government’s objectives including for employment and growth. That ordering of the FPC’s
objectives helps lean against short-term pressures to go for growth today at the cost of instability tomorrow.
In effect, the FPC provides the long-sightedness necessary to preserve future stability at a time when private
risk horizons may be shortening. And it provides necessary insurance against future tail risks at a time when
these tails may be fattening.

This macro-prudential regime, with the FPC at its centrepiece, is an explicitly institutional solution to the
financial policy dilemma. It is regulation of the system for the system: of the system because the FPC’s
focus is system-wide; for the system because the FPC’s aim is stability in the wider economy.
Macro-prudential policy protects the financial system from itself and the wider economy from its
consequences.

The FPC’s actions to date have been completely consistent with those objectives. For example, it has called
for UK banks to increase their capital levels to safeguard their future resiliance. It has also relaxed liquid
assets requirements for UK banks to support future growth. Through these actions, the FPC has sought to
protect the financial system from itself and the wider economy from its consequences.

In future, the FPC will have at its disposal a Countercyclical Capital Buffer (CCB) and Sectoral Capital
Requirements (SCR). These are designed explicitly to lean against financial cycles. Like monetary policy,
they operate symmetrically to constrain credit booms and cushion busts. They help safeguard today’s
younger generation from the impatient grasp of their parents and grandparents, to avoid the ultimate deceit.


The FPC can also invest in financial public goods – for example, new financial infrastructure to support
resilience. In the past, central banks helped build market infrastructures such as payment, clearing and
settlement systems to support resilience. Like lampposts and language, these are classic public goods. In
future, the FPC may wish to help build other types of market infrastructure - for example, securitisation
markets - to help create a more diverse financial system.

The FPC can also invest in financial public goods – for example, new financial infrastructure to support
resilience. In the past, central banks helped build market infrastructures such as payment, clearing and
settlement systems to support resilience. Like lampposts and language, these are classic public goods. In
future, the FPC may wish to help build other types of market infrastructure - for example, securitisation
markets - to help create a more diverse financial system.

A number of other countries have also now embarked on a macro-prudential mission, in both advanced and
emerging countries, often in response to crisis. The Financial Stability Board has recently set out some
design principles for these macro-prudential regimes.5 Interestingly, not all of these regimes have central
banks at the helm (IMF (2011)).

In a recent study, the IMF found that macro-prudential regimes which gave central banks an important role
were associated with more timely use of macro-prudential instruments (Lim et al. (2013)). That underscores
the importance of an appropriate institutional solution to the myopia trap. The institutional framework for
macro-prudential policy may have further to travel internationally if this trap is to be avoided in future.

Conclusion

In The Rock, T S Eliot wrote:

“Where is the wisdom we have lost in knowledge?
Where is the knowledge we have lost in information?”


Today’s information-rich world may have come at the expense of knowledge and wisdom, including about
the fat-tailed risks which may threaten social, economic and financial systems in the future. The

worst-in-a-lifetime financial crisis of the past few years is exhibit one. It is unlikely to be the last.

Yet the history of political and economic progress offers a clue to solving these problems. This has relied
heavily on long-lived, far-sighted institutions which are able to tackle the problems complex, integrated,
information-rich societies throw up. Post-crisis financial reform has recognised that, giving system-wide
regulatory responsibilities to a set of arms-length, long-lived institutions.

5 See FSB (2011), “Macroprudential policy tools and frameworks”.

All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx


There are many other areas of public policy where long-tailed risks loom large – pandemics, cyber risks,
trade disputes, carbon emissions. Left to their own devices, societies may under-insure against these tail
risks too. That is why institutions matter, now more than ever. They explain why nations failed in the past.
They may be even more important in helping them succeed in the future.

There are many other areas of public policy where long-tailed risks loom large – pandemics, cyber risks,
trade disputes, carbon emissions. Left to their own devices, societies may under-insure against these tail
risks too. That is why institutions matter, now more than ever. They explain why nations failed in the past.
They may be even more important in helping them succeed in the future.


Chart 1: Flows of capital, goods and services

Chart 1: Flows of capital, goods and services

25 180
160

20

External financial assets/GDP (RHS)
Trade/GDP (LHS) (a)
140
120

15

100
80

10

60
40

5

20
0

0

1870 1900 1914 1930 1960 1985 1990 2005

Sources: Maddison (1995: pg 227,239), IMF International Financial
Statistics, World Bank WDI, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Mckeown (2004 P 184) and Bank calculations.

(a) Trade is volume of exports.
Chart 3: Credit and GDP cycles in the UK

Per cent

Credit GDP
25
20
15
10
5

+
0
-

5

10

15

20

1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

Source: Bank calculations.

Chart 2: Global capital market integration


Perfect capital market integration

-0.2

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

Financial Autarky

1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

Sources: Taylor (2002), IMF WEO, Obstfeld and Taylor (2004)
and Bank Calculations

(a) Global capital market integration is the correlation
coefficient between domestic savings and investment for 15
countries (the sample varies slightly over the period)
14

All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx 14


References

References

Acemoglu, D, Ozdaglar, A and Tahbaz-Salehi, A (2013), “Systemic risk and stability in financial networks”.
NBER Working Paper No. 18727.

Aikman, D, Haldane, A and Nelson, B (2010), “Curing the Credit Cycle”, Columbia University Centre on
Capitalism and Society Annual Conference “Micro foundations for Modern Macroeconomics” New York.
Available at: http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2010/speech463.pdf

Alloy, B and Ahrens, A (1987), “Depression and pessimism for the future: Biased use of statistically
relevant information in predictions for self versus others” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol
52(2), pp. 366-378.

Arthur, W B (2009) ‘The nature of technology: what it is and how its evolves”, Penguin.
Banerjee, A and Duflo, E (2011), “Poor economics”, PublicAffairs.
Barro, R and Gordon, J (1983), “A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model”, Journal of


Political Economy, Vol. 91, No.4 pp 589-610.
Barton, D (2011), “Capitalism for the long term”, Harvard Business Review, March.
Bernanke, B (2004), “The great moderation”, remarks at the Eastern Economic Association, Washington,


DC, 20 February.
Carr, N (2011), “The shallows: what the internet is doing to our brains”, Atlantic Books.
Claessens, S, Kose, M A and Terrones, E M (2008), “What happens during recessions, crunches and


busts?”, IMF Working Paper, WP/08/274.
Coase, R (1960), “The problem of social cost” Journal of Law and Economics Vol. 3 pp. 1-44.
Coase, R (1990), “The firm, the market and the law” University of Chicago Press.
Coase, R (1995), “Essays on economics and economists”, University of Chicago Press.
Coffey, S F, Gudleski, G D, Saladin, M E and Brady, K T (2003), ‘Impulsivity and rapid discounting of


delayed hypothetical rewards in cocaine- dependent individuals’, Experimental and Clinical


Psychopharmacology, Vol. 11, No. 1, 18–25.
Crockett, A (2000), ‘Marrying the micro- and macroprudential dimensions of financial stability’, BIS
Speeches, September.


Cukier, K and Mayer-Schoenberger, V (2013), “Big Data: A revolution that will transform how we live, work


and think”, John Murray.
Davies, R, Haldane, A G, Nielsen, M and Pezzini, S (2013), “Measuring the costs of short-termism”,
Journal of Financial Stability.


Davenport, T, Paul B and Randy B (2012), “How 'Big Data' is different”, MIT Sloan Management Review
54, no. 1.
The Economist (2010), “Data, data everywhere”, The Economist Available at:


http://www.economist.com/node/15557443

All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx


Eliot, T S (1934), “The Rock: A Pageant Play”. London: Faber.

Eliot, T S (1934), “The Rock: A Pageant Play”. London: Faber.

http://www.jstor.org/stable/pdfplus/1942704.pdf?acceptTC=true

FSB (2011), “Macroprudential policy tools and frameworks”. Report to G20 Finance Ministers and Central
Bank Governors. Available at:

http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_1103.pdf

FSB (2013), “Financial regulatory factors affecting the availability of long – term investment finance”, Report
to G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors. Available at:

http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_130216a.pdf

Gai, P and Kapadia, S (2010), “Contagion in financial networks”, Proceedings of the Royal Society A, Vol.
466, No. 2120, pp. 2401-2423.

Gordon, R (2012), “Is U.S. economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds”, NBER
Working Paper Series, No. 18315.

Group of 30 (2013), “Long–term finance and economic growth”, Group of Thirty. Available at:

http://www.group30.org/images/PDF/Long-term_Finance_lo-res.pdf

Haldane, A (2009), “Rethinking the financial network”, Speech delivered at the Financial Student
Association, Amsterdam. Available at:

http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/archive/Documents/historicpubs/speeches/2009/speech386.pdf

Haldane, A (2010), “Patience and finance”, Oxford China Business Forum, Beijing. Available at:

http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2010/speech445.pdf

Haldane, A and May, R (2011), “Systemic risk in banking ecosystems”, Nature, Vol. 469, No. 7330.

http://www.nature.com/nature/journal/v469/n7330/full/nature09659.html

Haldane, A and Nelson, B (2012), “Tails of the unexpected”, Given at “The Credit Crisis Five Years On:
Unpacking the Crisis”, conference held at the University of Edinburgh Business School, 8-9 June. Available
at: http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2012/speech582.pdf

Hilbert, M and Lopez, P (2012), “How to measure the world’s technological capacity to communicate, store
and compute information; Part 1L Results and Scope”, International Journal of Communication No.6, pp.
956-979.

IMF (2011), “Macroprudential policy: an organizing framework”, Prepared by Monetary and Capital Markets
Department.

Jorgenson, D, Mun S H, and Stiroh, K J (2008), “A retrospective look at the U.S. productivity growth
resurgence”. Journal of Economic Perspectives 22, No. 1, pp. 3-24.

Jorda, O, Schularick, M and Taylor A (2012) “When credit bites back: leverage, business cycles, and
crisis”. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper Series, No. 2011-27.

Kahneman, D (2011), ‘Thinking, fast and slow”, Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

Kose, M A, Prasad, E, Rogoff, K and Wei, S J (2006), ‘Financial globalization: a reappraisal’ IMF Working
Paper, WP/06/189. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp06189.pdf

Kydland, F and Prescott, E (1977), “Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans”. The
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85, Issue 3, pp. 473-492.

All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx


Laibson, D (1997), “Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
112, pp. 443-478.


Lim, C H, Krznar, I, Lipinsky, F, Otani, A and Wu, X (2013), “The macroprudential framework: policy
responsiveness and institutional arrangements”, IMF Working Paper, WP/13/166.


Maddison, A (1995), “Monitoring the world economy, 1820 – 1992”, OECD Publishing.


Newman, M E J (2005), “Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf’s law”, Contemporary Physics, Vol. 46,
No. 5, pp. 323-351.


Nier, E, Osinki, J, Jacome, L and Madrid, P (2011), “Institutional models for macroprudential policy”, IMF
Staff Discussion Note, SDN/11/18.
North, D (1981), “Structure and change in economic history”, W.W. Norton & Company.


North, D (1991), “Institutions”, The Journal of Economic Perspective, Vol. 5, No.1, pp 97-112.
Olson, M (1982), “The rise and decline of nations: economic growth, stagflation and social rigidities”, Yale
University Press.


Olson, M (1991), “Autocracy, democracy, and prosperity”. In Strategy and choice, edited by Zeckhauser, R


J. Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 131-57.
Reinhart, C and Rogoff, K, (2009), “This time is different: eight centuries of financial crises” Princeton
University Press.
Sachs, J (2005), “The end of poverty: How we can make it happen in our lifetime”, Penguin.
Simon, H A (1971), ‘Designing organizations for an information-rich world’ in: Martin Greenberger,


“Computers, Communication, and the Public Interest”, pp 38-52, John Hopkins Press.
Smith, A (1759), “The theory of moral sentiments”, London: A. Millar.
Veblen, T (1899), “The theory of the leisure class: an economic study of institutions”, Macmillan and


Company, New York.
Watts, D (2002), ‘A simple model of global cascades on random networks” Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, Vol. 99, No. 9. Available at:


http://www.pnas.org/content/99/9/5766.full

World Bank (2008), “Globalization and international trade”, World Trade Report. Available at:

http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/anrep_e/wtr08-2b_e.pdf

All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx



Add a Comment

Comment Guidelines

We encourage you to use comments to engage with other users, share your perspective and ask questions of authors and each other. However, in order to maintain the high level of discourse we’ve all come to value and expect, please keep the following criteria in mind:  

  •            Enrich the conversation, don’t trash it.

  •           Stay focused and on track. Only post material that’s relevant to the topic being discussed. 

  •           Be respectful. Even negative opinions can be framed positively and diplomatically. Avoid profanity, slander or personal attacks directed at an author or another user. Racism, sexism and other forms of discrimination will not be tolerated.

  • Use standard writing style. Include punctuation and upper and lower cases. Comments that are written in all caps and contain excessive use of symbols will be removed.
  • NOTE: Spam and/or promotional messages and comments containing links will be removed. Phone numbers, email addresses, links to personal or business websites, Skype/Telegram/WhatsApp etc. addresses (including links to groups) will also be removed; self-promotional material or business-related solicitations or PR (ie, contact me for signals/advice etc.), and/or any other comment that contains personal contact specifcs or advertising will be removed as well. In addition, any of the above-mentioned violations may result in suspension of your account.
  • Doxxing. We do not allow any sharing of private or personal contact or other information about any individual or organization. This will result in immediate suspension of the commentor and his or her account.
  • Don’t monopolize the conversation. We appreciate passion and conviction, but we also strongly believe in giving everyone a chance to air their point of view. Therefore, in addition to civil interaction, we expect commenters to offer their opinions succinctly and thoughtfully, but not so repeatedly that others are annoyed or offended. If we receive complaints about individuals who take over a thread or forum, we reserve the right to ban them from the site, without recourse.
  • Only English comments will be allowed.
  • Any comment you publish, together with your investing.com profile, will be public on investing.com and may be indexed and available through third party search engines, such as Google.

Perpetrators of spam or abuse will be deleted from the site and prohibited from future registration at Investing.com’s discretion.

Write your thoughts here
 
Are you sure you want to delete this chart?
 
Post
Post also to:
 
Replace the attached chart with a new chart ?
1000
Your ability to comment is currently suspended due to negative user reports. Your status will be reviewed by our moderators.
Please wait a minute before you try to comment again.
Thanks for your comment. Please note that all comments are pending until approved by our moderators. It may therefore take some time before it appears on our website.
 
Are you sure you want to delete this chart?
 
Post
 
Replace the attached chart with a new chart ?
1000
Your ability to comment is currently suspended due to negative user reports. Your status will be reviewed by our moderators.
Please wait a minute before you try to comment again.
Add Chart to Comment
Confirm Block

Are you sure you want to block %USER_NAME%?

By doing so, you and %USER_NAME% will not be able to see any of each other's Investing.com's posts.

%USER_NAME% was successfully added to your Block List

Since you’ve just unblocked this person, you must wait 48 hours before renewing the block.

Report this comment

I feel that this comment is:

Comment flagged

Thank You!

Your report has been sent to our moderators for review
Continue with Google
or
Sign up with Email