Get 40% Off
🤯 This Tech Portfolio is up 29% YTD! Join Now to Get April’s Top PicksGet The Picks – Just 99 USD

Book Review: Money, Blood And Revolution

Published 04/21/2014, 05:19 AM
Updated 07/09/2023, 06:31 AM

George Cooper’s Money, Blood and Revolution: How Darwin and the Doctor of King Charles I Could Turn Economics into a Science (Harriman House, 2014) is a quick read but a much longer think. I’m still in the thinking process.

Thomas Kuhn’s landmark work, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (1962), provides the theoretical underpinning to Cooper’s book. In Part I Cooper recaps Kuhn’s hypothesis and illustrates it (as well as the paradigm shift he proposes in economics) with the work of four scientific revolutionaries: Copernicus, Harvey, Darwin, and Wegener. “In all cases, the path to scientific progress required overturning the equilibrium paradigm and moving to a dynamic, usually circulatory, paradigm. Copernicus made the earth circulate around the sun. Harvey made blood circulate around the body. Darwin made species evolve and Wegener made continents move, pushed by circulating currents within the earth’s core.” (p. 76)

Economics, Cooper argues, is not yet a science; instead, it “exhibits all of the symptoms of being in one of Thomas Kuhn’s states of pre-revolutionary scientific crisis.” (p. 81) For instance, it has fractured into too many incompatible schools of thought with incommensurable paradigms. Cooper analyzes—and criticizes—the most widely recognized of these schools: classical, neoclassical, libertarian, monetarist, Keynesian, Austrian, Marxist, institutional, and behavioral. Moreover, although the mathematical models of economics are proliferating and their complexity growing, “their predictive ability is not obviously improving.” (p. 82) Economics, in brief, is ripe for revolution.

The first ingredient of economics, if it is to be truly scientific, must be Darwin’s notion of competition. Unfortunately, if human beings are Darwinian competitors rather than neoclassical optimizers, the basic tenets of neoclassical economics (individualism, maximization, and equilibrium) crumble. People do not make their decisions based on their own self-interest, independently of one another, and these decisions are not always designed to maximize their own welfare. Once the first two principles fall, the principle of equilibrium—that “the result of all of these individual optimizing decisions is a stable system in optimal equilibrium”—falls as well.

As Cooper recapitulates: “If human decision-making is fundamentally a competitive process, then decisions of individuals become dependent upon those of their peers. This implies that behaviour at the aggregate level of the economy cannot be reliably modelled as the sum of individual behaviours. Nor can it be safely assumed that the behaviours of individuals in competition will lead to an equilibrium situation. Indeed it is likely that competitive actors will always seek to disturb any equilibrium.” (p. 133)

The second element in Cooper’s paradigm shift, with a nod to William Harvey, is a circulatory model of economic growth. This model comes from marrying the competitive Darwinian economic system with the democratic political system. Capitalism pushes wealth up the social pyramid while democracy, with its progressive taxation, acts in the opposite direction to push it back down, “causing a vigorous circulatory flow of wealth throughout the economy.” (p. 152) This model, sure to rile people on both sides of the political aisle, suggests that income inequality is essential for economic growth and that taxation and government spending are contributors to economic progress. That is, “economic progress is associated with both income inequality and large government.” (p. 157)

Cooper concludes by using the circulatory growth model to help explain the causes of the financial crisis and “why the policy mix applied after the crisis has failed to restore normal levels of economic growth.” (p. 169) He offers three suggestions for dealing with the current economic stagnation: “1. Stop the policies designed to promote further private-sector debt-accumulation” such as student debt, “2. Shift from monetary to Keynesian stimulus” because quantitative easing “puts the money into the wrong position within the circulatory system,” and “3. Rebalance the burden of taxation between labour and capital—less tax on labour, more tax on capital.” (p. 191)

Cooper may not be the Darwin of economics, but I suspect that he (and the many researchers who are exploring complex adaptive systems) will help point the way.

By way of a footnote, readers who are interested in learning more about complex systems science might want to check out Melanie Mitchell’s course, Introduction to Complexity, part of a project being developed by the Santa Fe Institute and funded by a grant from the John Templeton Foundation.

Latest comments

Risk Disclosure: Trading in financial instruments and/or cryptocurrencies involves high risks including the risk of losing some, or all, of your investment amount, and may not be suitable for all investors. Prices of cryptocurrencies are extremely volatile and may be affected by external factors such as financial, regulatory or political events. Trading on margin increases the financial risks.
Before deciding to trade in financial instrument or cryptocurrencies you should be fully informed of the risks and costs associated with trading the financial markets, carefully consider your investment objectives, level of experience, and risk appetite, and seek professional advice where needed.
Fusion Media would like to remind you that the data contained in this website is not necessarily real-time nor accurate. The data and prices on the website are not necessarily provided by any market or exchange, but may be provided by market makers, and so prices may not be accurate and may differ from the actual price at any given market, meaning prices are indicative and not appropriate for trading purposes. Fusion Media and any provider of the data contained in this website will not accept liability for any loss or damage as a result of your trading, or your reliance on the information contained within this website.
It is prohibited to use, store, reproduce, display, modify, transmit or distribute the data contained in this website without the explicit prior written permission of Fusion Media and/or the data provider. All intellectual property rights are reserved by the providers and/or the exchange providing the data contained in this website.
Fusion Media may be compensated by the advertisers that appear on the website, based on your interaction with the advertisements or advertisers.
© 2007-2024 - Fusion Media Limited. All Rights Reserved.